Books of the year

Every year at this time, I look back at the books that I have reviewed during the year on this blog. 

Let me start with the The Big Con: How the Consulting Industry Weakens our Businesses, Infantilises our Governments and Warps our Economies. by Mariana Mazzucato and Rosie Collington.

Mazzucato has built up a big reputation for espousing the benefits of public investment and the public sector over the private. scanning her popularity from the left in the labour movement through to mainstream governments in Europe and Latin America. In this new book, Mazzucato and Collington expose the scam that the management consultancy business is.

Their premise is that consulting is really a confidence trick. “A consultant’s job is to convince anxious customers that they have the answers, whether or not that’s true”.  The authors point out that governments and companies everywhere rely on consultancies, companies that ‘talk the talk’ but know little about the problems they claim to solve.  Billions are parted everywhere to the likes of McKinsey and other ‘management consultancies’ with little resulting benefit. The ‘management consultancy con’ is really a product of neo-liberal ideology that the private sector knows best and will be more efficient than public sector workers doing the job.  Mazzucato and Collington expose the scam but are vague about what to do about it.  Still an eye-opening book on the myth that work for profit is more ‘efficient’ than work for need.

Branco Milanovic is the world’s greatest expert on global inequality of wealth and income.  In 2023 he published yet another book, Visions of Inequality.

This takes a different approach from analysing the stats on inequality.  Instead Milanovic discusses those he considers provide the most important explanations of why inequality of wealth and income is so great between humans.  As Milanovic puts it: “The objective of this book is to trace the evolution of thinking about economic inequality over the past two centuries, based on the works of some influential economists whose writings can be interpreted to deal, directly or indirectly, with income distribution and income inequality. They are François Quesnay, Adam Smith, David Ricardo, Karl Marx, Vilfredo Pareto, Simon Kuznets, and a group of economists from the second half of the twentieth century (the latter collectively influential even as they individually lack the iconic status of the prior six).” The latter includes Thomas Piketty.

In my review, I concentrated on Milanovic’s account of Marx’s view. Milanovic unfortunately accepts many misconceptions about Marx’s value theory and the law of the tendency of the rate of profit to fall, which I think leads him to conclude that a falling rate of profit will mean reduced inequality because it is the rise in real wages that lowers profitability.  I think this confuses the rate of surplus value with the rate of profit.

Nevertheless, Milanovic correctly argues that Marx considered that any distribution of income and consumption was only a consequence of the distribution of the conditions of production. The capitalist mode of production rests on the fact that the material conditions of production are in the hands of non-workers in the form of property in capital and land, while the masses are only owners of their personal condition of production, of labor power. Thus, the distribution of income and wealth cannot be changed in any material way until the system is changed. “To clamor for equal or even equitable remuneration on the basis of the wages system,” Marx writes, “is the same as to clamor for freedom on the basis of the slavery system.”

“For all that we are told we live in an increasingly dematerialised world where ever more value lies in intangible items – apps and networks and online services – the physical world continues to underpin everything else.”  So starts Ed Conway, economics editor at the British Sky TV channel, in his fascinating little book, Material World.

The vast bulk of the world economy is still built on the production of things, ‘stuff’ that can be commodified from the labour of billions. The material world, as Conway calls it, is still the basis of the global economy. Conway singles out just six key materials that drive the world economy in the 21st century: sand, salt, iron, copper, oil and lithium.  They are the most widely used and the very hardest to replace.  In the book, Conway takes us on a journey of history and technology surrounding these key resources.

Conway notes two things that Marx’s value theory predicts – of course, unknowingly. “As the amount of stuff we remove from the ground and turn into extraordinary products continues to increase, the proportion of people needed to make this happen decreases.”  Thus there is a continual rise in what Marx called the organic composition of capital.  

And the other is that capitalist production takes no account of what mainstream economics calls ‘externalities’, the ‘collateral damage’ to the environment for humans and the rest of the planet. “There are no environmental accounts or material flow analysis, which count only the refined metal. When it comes to even the United Nations’ measures of how much humans are affecting the planet, this waste rock doesn’t count.” Conway ends his book with the great contradiction of the 21st century: global warming and climate change.  How can the world get to ‘net zero’ when it needs so many raw material resources? 

Can technology do the trick?  This is the issue that Daren Acemoglu poses in his book, Power and Progress – a thousand- year struggle over technology and prosperity’, jointly authored with Simon Johnson.  Acemoglu is a leading economist on the impact of technology on jobs, people and economies. I have referred to his work before in various posts.

In Power and Progress, we get a sweeping historical account of how technology has taken humanity forward in terms of living standards but also often created misery, poverty and increased inequality. The book considers what can be done to ensure that the gains from the productivity ‘bandwagon’ of modern technology like robots, automation and AI can be spread among the many and not just garnered by the few. 

The authors fall back on the ‘policy levers’ of taxation and subsidies to research; regulation of markets; the breaking up of the big tech monopolies; and stronger trade unions. All these measures in one form or another have failed sufficiently to achieve the spread of the gains of technology in the past and would for the current innovations – assuming these policies were ever to be implemented.  What Power and Progress tells us about technology and its impact on our lives, for good or bad, is that whoever has the power gets the benefit.

On the same theme of the impact of technology, Matteo Pasquinelli authors a book called In the eye of the master, which argues that, whereas in the past labour was supervised and controlled by the masters ( the owners and their agents, the managers), now supervision will be increasingly automated.  So, instead of AI and automation being used collectively by us all, machines will rule our lives for the benefit of the master.

The theme of an increasingly authoritarian state is raised in a new book, entitled, The rise and fall of American Finance by Stephen Maher and Scott Aquanno.

The authors argue that the ‘financialisation’ of capitalism since the 1980s has not weakened the capitalist mode of production but changed and strengthened its ability to exploit with the support of “an increasingly authoritarian state.”  The authors claimed that they were arguing differently from “strict financialist theorists” by not claiming “a qualitatively new phase of capitalist development is emerging” but just the same interlocking of finance, industry and the state that has always existed in capitalism. 

What to do about this authoritarian state?   The authors’ policy conclusions are vague, namely that: “reducing economic inequality and bringing investment in “Good Jobs” back to the United States requires challenging the competitive logic of global financial integration with state-imposed barriers on the movement of investment worldwide.”  Or to be clearer: “establishing a greater public role in determining the allocation of investment”.  That seems somewhat feeble if capitalism is taking a more repressive formation.

Two of my book reviews have caused some controversy among readers and others.  The first is Dependency theory after 50 years, by Claudio Katz.  Katzo delivers a comprehensive account of dependency theory as expounded mainly in Latin America over the last 50 years.  

Dependency theory is really a theory of imperialism.  Dependency’ can take different meanings but in essence it identifies two main groups of countries in the global economic system: the core and the periphery. The core countries are wealthy countries that control the global economy. The periphery countries are poor countries that are dependent on the core countries for trade, investment and technology. ie prosperity. 

Katz concentrates his account of dependency theory on its Marxist variant, which argues that these countries will remain ‘dependent’ because of the huge extraction of value from labour in their economies to the imperialist bloc through trade, finance and technology.  What Katz does show is that Marx’s value theory of “productive globalization based on the exploitation of workers remodels the cleavages between center and periphery through transfers of surplus value.” And it is “the omission of that mechanism prevents the critics of dependency from understanding the logic of underdevelopment.”  

I have got some stick from supporters of the theory because of my criticism in my review of Brazilian Marxist economist Ruy Mauro Marini who developed a theory of ‘super-exploitation’ and the idea of ‘sub imperialism’, ie small imperialist countries.  Even though I have doubts about the validity of these two concepts in explaining modern imperialism, Katz does show how Marini seemed close to a classic Marxist view that imperialist gains are a product of ‘unequal exchange’ in international trade and the general extraction of surplus value from the periphery.

Long standing Marxist scholar, Fred Moseley presented a new book entitled Marx’s theory value in, Chapter one of capital: a critique of Michael Heinrich’s value form interpretation.  The book discussed the debate over the meaning of the value form of commodities under capitalism. 

Moseley interprets Marx to argue that there is a common property of all commodities that determines their value, namely the objectified abstract human labour contained in commodity production. Leading Marxist scholar Michael Heinrich argues, on the other hand, that labour in production is only concrete labour and abstract labour comes to exist only in exchange.

It’s a complicated plot but the debate does have important implications for our understanding of capitalism.  For me, Marx’s analysis of the value in a commodity is about showing the fundamental contradiction in capitalism between production for social need (use-value) and production for profit (exchange value).  Units of production (or commodities under capitalism) have that dual character which epitomises that contradiction.   In my view, Heinrich loses that contradiction by arguing that Marx meant a commodity only has value when it is sold for money on the market and not before in production through the exploitation of human labour.

It is no accident that Heinrich dismisses Marx law of profitability as illogical, ‘indeterminate’ and irrelevant to explaining crises and instead looks excessive credit and financial instability as causes.  Heinrich even claims that Marx dropped his law of profitability – although the evidence for that is non-existent.  If profits (surplus value) from production by human labour disappear from any analysis to be replaced by profits from exchange for money, then we no longer have a Marxist theory of crisis or any theory of crisis at all.

19 thoughts on “Books of the year

  1. Regarding realisation in production or exchange – human labour is bought on the market before production begins – human labour is the ur-commodity and where Marx’s theory of alienation (reification) meets his theory of surplus value…(subject and object in Hegelese lol)

  2. Off topic but too important news to be forgotten:

    “China in full swing to promote new industrialization: minister”
    http://en.people.cn/n3/2023/1228/c90000-20115672.html

    [The People Daily is the official newspaper of the Central Committee of the Chinese Communist Party]

    The first line of the article: “China will vigorously promote new industrialization amid efforts to advance Chinese modernization, Minister of Industry and Information Technology Jin Zhuanglong said at a symposium Wednesday.”

    This “new industrialization” definitely signs China will not to with the (post/neo)Keynesian theory of the “Middle Income Trap”. They are going full-socialism, i.e. develop the productive forces further.

    The novelty here is the historical context: we are living in what the Democratic Socialists of the USA call “Late Capitalism”, an era where capitalism, in order to survive as a mode of production, has to, as a tendency , undevelop the productive forces. This means that, for the first time in China’s history (1949-present), China will attempt to surpass the capitalist world technologically and industrially (become the vanguard of the development of the productive forces; in other words, the main actor of History).

    Now, two outcomes are possible: either China fails or succeeds with this “new industrialization”. If it fails, it will be an indication that the actual level of the productive forces of capitalism are still not at the critical level necessary to ignite an irreversible change to communism (socialism), and that socialism is further from our reach than the Marxist-Leninists or pro-China theorists thought (it would be also excellent news for the Western Marxists, since that would confirm their theory that the key to communism is in the West and not the East). If it succeeds, then we can basically pop the champagne, because that would be a strong sign the socialist era has already begun — only that it begun too slowly and too far away (USSR -> China) for us in the West to perceive it.

      1. These steps are necessary:

        1. the American Empire must fall;

        2. the BRI and the Common Shared Destiny must prevail;

        3. China must no collapse a la USSR;

        4. The Russian Federation must not betray China and, even better, must re-Sovietize (reinstall socialism);

        5. All of the above must happen without a nuclear holocaust.

        6. “New industrialization” succeeds.

      2. Aside from the destruction of all failed fake socialist states and social democracy democratically and nonviolently voted in all wealthy nations and massive restriction of human consumption to save nature, it’s hard to guess how Anti-Capital would answer this question. Even a vague posture of philosophical purity, the tactical presentation, might be of interest?

        Personally, my post-it note program is 1)kill all the billionaires and 2)unilateral disarmament of the US. The sermonette version is 1)production for use 2)abolition of classes 3)national self-determination doesn’t mean having its own army and currency and 4)plan the transition to a sustainable world economy to save all of us—and that may even mean, scary as that is, geoengineering projects. Socialism is not even an ending, much less a guaranteed happy ending.

        Sorry, vk but…
        1.The US will never fall, it must be pushed and no one is pushing. Well, except DPR Korea and everyone else hates that Korea with a passion hotter than the sun, much preferring the cannibal kingdom. What is the slogan, “Squid Game Rules!”
        2.The BRI will not give world capitalism a new lease on life…and if “Common Shared Destiny” means BRICS et al., once again, that’s not a thing, it’s a string of letters.
        3.The more millionaires and billionaires there are, the more the capital market makes all the investment decisions and the more the provinces are self-financing, the weaker the PRC gets. It won’t collapse the same way the USSR did, but if it did collapse capitalist restoration will be even more violent and induce an even worse population collapse than Yeltsin did.
        4.The Russian Federation is anti-Communist which is why turning on the PRC is not betrayal. It’s being true to oneself. And socialism will not be reinstalled on one man’s whim.
        5.Oddly, sort of agree. Nuclear holocaust as the terminal phase of hybrid WWIII however is not just up to the socialist forces, it is up to the crazies who believe in capitalism+whatever deranged hobbies they’ve invested in (mostly crank fascist stylings, I think, but libertarians aren’t gone yet.) I do feel compelled to add, avoiding nuclear holocaust is much less likely if you think the losing imperialists must be pacified. There’s not enough money in the world to buy all of them off.

      3. “Aside from the destruction of all failed fake socialist states and social democracy democratically and nonviolently voted in all wealthy nations and massive restriction of human consumption to save nature, it’s hard to guess how Anti-Capital would answer this question. Even a vague posture of philosophical purity, the tactical presentation, might be of interest?”

        You know mandm tried accusing me of one or two of these same things and when I challenged him to produce a single sentence I ever wrote confirming his nonsense claims, he went curiously silent.

        Same challenge goes for SJ, although I’m sure he’s so full of himself (and bullshit) he won’t withdraw from spreading more of his garbage.

        So SJ your mission should you choose to accept it is to produce a single document authored by me in which I have advocated destruction of all, or ANY, “failed fake socialist states”–your description; or proposed the “voting” in of social democracy in all wealthy nations; ever advocated massive restrictions on human consumption.

        You can check the archives here; or at thewolfatthedoor.blogspot.com; or at anticapital0.wordpress.com

      4. It is not an accident that Anti-Capital cannot, even when invited to do so, offer any words at all about what wonderful policies and ideals Anti-Capital favors. If Anti-Capital resents people drawing rational conclusions from what Anti-Capital attacks, the solution is not to demand footnotes, much less the reading of Anti-Capital’s collected works. It is to simply say, what in a usefully specific context like this very thread—that’s why platitudes won’t do, incidentally—Anti-Capital just needs to say what what Anti-Capital would consider success. I think Anti-Capital can’t offer any thoughts about successful reforms in socialist states because Anti-Capital is committed to their overthrow. And Anti-Capital has no useful thoughts about successful industrialization because Anti-Capital basically sees consumption as the problem. And Anti-Capital can’t admit to being just another social democrat because Social Democrats are, in today’s politics, Sir Keir Starmer and Tony Blair or Obama and Biden.

        Do I think wrong about what Anti-Capital’s negative critique says? Again, just refute it by saying what Anti-Capital does positively stand for?

        It’s not hard, I modeled an example of being upfront about such things. vk offered an actual answer, which I at least acknowledged albeit with criticism.

      5. SJ, channeling the late Richard J. Daley former mayor of Chicago, wants to know what trees do I plant?… as if I’m under some obligation to explain what I stand for to someone who simply makes shit up.

        I’m not.

      6. The reason for giving some positive account of what Anti-Capital stands for is not to satisfy me, but everyone else. It’s like someone asking a scientific creationist to give their explanations for the multiplication of species or to explain why fossils show this actually happened.

    1. Apparently, my question was misunderstood.

      I intended my question to focus on the “new industrialization.

      What are the elements of this program?
      How does this program differ from previous industrialization programs?
      What measures will be employed to measure progress in reaching the program goals?
      What is proposed as the time frame?

    2. The ‘new industrialization’ is not so new, I searched on Chinese gov. web, and found this page from 2016
      https://www.gov.cn/xinwen/2016-06/24/content_5085041.htm (it’s in Chinese but I guess a normal web translator would do it).
      Also this one is from September last year
      https://www.gov.cn/zhengce/202309/content_6906121.htm

      And there are some other articles on the gov. web about new industrialization, mostly writing about the industry stats and how the works are progressing. Actually most our gov work reports look like that, what have been done and what is going to be done, I do not regularly read them so not sure if there is a big change.

      Just leave some information, I’m not good at economics and english.

      1. What caught my attention is not the content per se, but the historical context.

        1) the Chinese, at the highest governmental level (and, being a socialist country, the highest level of the de facto commanding heights of the country — which is not the case in the capitalist countries), openly speak about it and they gave a name to it (even if very generic);

        2) I don’t think this is common practice in the Western democracies for the government to give its people an update of the entire industry of the nation. What I observe is politicians and parties make some manifesto which may or may not include the industry, and, sometimes, they propagandize some big building project (e.g. a high-speed railway, a new port, a new football stadium) in the year before the elections. This is understandable, because a government from a Western democracy doesn’t know if it will survive more than four years, and they won’t ignite a new industrialization process for which the opposition may take credit eight years later;

        3) in the context of the recent developments of the Chinese economy, it is relevant that this “new industrialization” automatically expels the possibility of adoption of the “Middle Income Trap Theory”, which is absolute consensus in contemporary bourgeois economics (both left-wing and right-wing). The Chinese are going through the path of non-financial “high-quality growth” which is clearly based on industrialization (surpass, once and forever, the West technologically). That in itself disproves the Trotskyite theory that China, post-Mao, is “neoliberal”.

        Of course that we should never say never in History: this new industrialization may fail epically; Xi Jinping may be toppled; a Chinese Gorbachev may rise; China may go through a shock therapy; and so on etc. etc. etc. — But the evidence we have today indicates China is socialist and will continue to be socialist, regardless of any Western interpretation of its economy or society.

  3. “Crisis theory, the law of the tendency of the rate of profit to fall and Marx’s studies in the 1870s”
    According to Heinrich, Marx failed to prove his thesis that the rate of profit must fall. The problem with Heinrich’s argument, however, is that Marx emphasised compensatory tendencies not as an exception to his thesis, but as the necessary result of the falling rate of profit.
    This is astonishing from a scholar of his calibre.
    Heinrich sees a contradiction between this observation and the law of the tendency of the rate of profit to fall.
    Illustrated in the third book.
    If this were the case, it would be a secondary reflection on Marx’s part, since the
    that the annotation comes after the writing of the manuscripts then published by Engels as the third book.
    It seems to me that Heinrich falls into an incredible misunderstanding for a
    student of his value.
    Capital having by effect a greater organic composition
    the introduction of an innovation in fact generates a higher individual profit because it appropriates an additional profit from competitors, by being able to sell at a price higher than the individual value of its product. But the same innovation reduces the average rate when the innovation is generalised and with it the greater organic composition.
    organic composition.
    In other words, the comparison between individual tests at a given moment becomes confused with the comparison between average profit rates at two successive moments, before and after the generalised introduction of labour-saving innovations.
    For Marx, the time factor and the impact of an initial investment over time play a fundamental role.

    Socialist production, for needs, chrematistic inverse M-A-M+.

  4. Could you venture an opinion on the article by economic historian Paul Schmelzing on the decline of interest rates earned on bonds or their equivalent over the past five hundred years? If the article is correct why did this happen?

    1. Just a few immediate thoughts. The maximum rate of interest (in real terms) is determined by the rate of profit on capital in Marxist theory, so if the rate of profit falls over the long term, so will the average rate of interest. The rate of interest on bonds before the widespread development of the capitalist mode of production is more related to demand for loans by the state and private lords and the availability of gold supply and hoarding. Under capitalist production, costs are increasingly determined by the rise in productivity and not by weather or agriculture, so prices have a long term tendency to fall and with them, interest rates. Any other views?

      1. Thanks for the quick response. I have no expertise on Marxian economics ( or any economics ) ….just interested. But your answer makes sense and was what I was thinking might be the cause or one of the causes.
        Supplemental question….
        On page 84 of your book Marx 200 there is a table re the transformation of value to price
        I followed the logic showing the prices for each sectors 1 to 5 which are all different based on equalization of profit rates but ?.. would there not be price competition driving all prices to one common lower value …. Or am I missing something ?
        Thanks

      2. We need to distinguish the general relationship between the rate of profit and interest. It does not always hold particularly at the end of the business cycle. Here we have a sharp contraction in profitability accompanied by a spike in interest rates as the chain of credit shatters. This forms the financial emergency which heralds the recession.

  5. Dear Michael, I would like to make a correction regarding the author who formulated the concept of super exploitation of labor: his name is Ruy Mauro Marini, and he is Brazilian and not Argentine.

Leave a comment

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.