G20 and the mainstream solutions to a global slowdown

The weekend meeting of the finance ministers of the top 20 economies in the world in Shanghai, China was a dismal affair.  Before the meeting, the IMF painted a grim picture of the state of the global economy.  In its, Global Prospects and Policy Challenges, the IMF economists warned that it would be reducing its forecasts for global economic growth in 2016, yet again.

And as the G20 summit met, figures came in for world trade in 2015.  It has recorded its biggest reversal since the Great Recession of 2008-9.  The value of goods that crossed international borders last year fell 13.8 per cent in dollar terms — the first contraction since 2009 — according to the Netherlands Bureau of Economic Policy Analysis’s World Trade Monitor.

world trade

The Baltic Dry index, a measure of global trade in bulk commodities, has been touching historic lows.  China, which in 2014 overtook the US as the world’s biggest trading nation, this month reported double-digit falls in both exports and imports in January. In Brazil, which is now experiencing its worst recession in more than a century, imports from China have collapsed.  Exports from China to Brazil of everything from cars to textiles shipped in containers fell 60 per cent in January from a year earlier while the total volume of imports via containers into Latin America’s biggest economy halved, according to Maersk Line, the world’s largest shipping company.

Measured in volume terms the picture was not as grim, with global trade growing 2.5 per cent. But that fell below global economic growth of 3.1 per cent, extending a depressing trend in the global economy. Before the 2008 crisis global trade grew at as much as twice the rate of global output for decades. Since 2011, however, trade growth has slowed to be in line with — or even below — the broader growth of the global economy, prompting some to raise questions about whether the globalisation that has been such a dominant feature for decades has peaked.

And if you strip out China, the economies of the so-called developing world are now growing more slowly than the developed world for the first time since 1999.  Emerging markets (EMs) ex-China eked out output growth of just 1.92 per cent last year, according to IMF data, below even the spluttering growth of the developed world, where output rose 1.98 per cent.

EM DM growth

This  underperformance of EMs vis-à-vis developed countries in per capita terms is starker still because population growth is faster in EMs than in DMs – indeed the latest census for Japan shows that it has lost 1m people in the last five years.

A Citibank economist commented “It’s called lack of convergence. The theory suggests that emerging markets ought to be growing faster than developed markets and catching up [but] I think [the emerging world] is probably going into a little bit of a recession now…The futures of billions of people will depend on whether this reversal of the trend towards convergence proves to be a blip, or whether it is instead the strong showing of emerging countries during the 2000-2014 period that ultimately turns out to have been anomalous.”

On the other hand, as I have argued before on this blog, we cannot confirm a new global slump unless the US economy also starts to contract.  And that is not happening yet.  In the latest reading for the last quarter of 2015, US real GDP rose at an annual rate of 1% and completed a rise of 2.4% in 2015, similar to that in the UK.  But US economic growth is decelerating, led by slowing business investment and losses on trade with the rest of the world.

It’s not looking good.   As Citibank economists put it, “It is likely, in our view, that global growth will this year once again underperform and, the risk of a global growth recession (growth below 2%) is high and rising.  Should the US economy falter, it would be difficult to identify any major economy that could be the growth engine for the world in the near-term.  And the forecast for US growth in 2016 has meanwhile gone from 3.0% in January 2015 to 2.0% most recently”.

In its G20 Surveillance Note (G20 Note) the IMF concluded that “There is less room for complacency now. Policymakers can and should act quickly to boost growth and plan to contain risks. Coordinating a strong policy response at the G20 level is just as urgent. The G20 must plan now and proactively identify policies that could be rolled out quickly, if downside risks materialize.”  At the G20 meeting itself, current Bank of England governor (the best-paid one in the world), Mark Carney reckoned that the “The global economy risks becoming trapped in a low-growth, low-inflation, low-interest rate equilibrium.”   The G20 ministers put a brave face on it in their communiqué: “The global recovery continues, but it remains uneven and falls short of our ambition for strong, sustainable and balanced growth,” it said.

So what is the way out of this global economic slowdown that threatens to turn into a new economic recession?  The search for new economic policy measures to avoid another global slump is on. We have had zero interest rates set by central banks to encourage businesses and people to borrow more; we have had quantitative easing (printing cash and giving it to the banks); now we are having negative interest rates (charging the banks for not lending their cash on to the real economy).  But it’s not working.

Indeed, at the G20, BoE governor Carney poured cold water over the current solution to the global slowdown offered by several central banks, namely negative interest rates.  These moves by central banks to cut interest rates below zero risked creating a “beggar-thy-neighbour” environment which could leave the global economy trapped in low growth.  Negative interest rates mean customers effectively pay a fee for parking cash in banks, so Japanese citizens are beginning to hoard yen, according to the Wall Street Journaland they need somewhere to put it.  Sales of safes have doubled from the same period a year earlier at chain hardware store, Shimachu, according to the Journal. The chain has already sold out of one model worth $700. Others savers are considering more unconventional storage spaces.  “In response to negative interest rates, there are elderly people who’re thinking of keeping their money under a mattress,”  So people are saving money rather than spending.

The G20 muses: “Monetary policies will continue to support economic activity and ensure price stability … but monetary policy alone cannot lead to balanced growth.” And as the IMF economists said “accommodative monetary policy, while still very much needed, cannot do it alone. There needs to be a comprehensive approach, including fiscal policy (where there is fiscal space) and balance sheet repair. ”

Without action, a new global financial crisis is certain to occur and without reform, it is likely to happen sooner rather than later, according to Carney’s predecessor, former Bank of England governor Mervyn King  in promoting his new book (The end of alchemy, the global economy and the future of money). King, who headed the BoE when the world’s financial system almost collapsed in 2008-09, said only a fundamental rethink of the monetary and banking systems could avert another crisis. “Without reform of the financial system, another crisis is certain, and the failure … to tackle the disequilibrium in the world economy makes it likely that it will come sooner rather than later,”

The majority view at the US Federal Reserve is not so pessimistic.  Vice Chair Stanley Fischer still hopes for US economic speed-up.  Fischer said: “If the recent financial market developments lead to a sustained tightening of financial conditions, they could signal a slowing in the global economy that could affect growth and inflation in the United States. But we have seen similar periods of volatility in recent years–including in the second half of 2011–that have left little visible imprint on the economy, and it is still early to judge the ramifications of the increased market volatility of the first seven weeks of 2016.” So it would be a mistake to launch NIRP in the US. Monetary policy should aim to avoid such risks and keep the expansion on a sustainable track”.

Nevertheless, the voices of doom among economists and policy makers are getting stronger.  So now the talk is for what is called ‘helicopter money’ (just handing over cash to households to spend) and/or fiscal stimulus (increased government spending and tax cuts).  I have commented before on the nature of ‘helicopter money’ named after the idea promoted originally by monetarist economist Milton Friedman and his follower, former Federal Reserve chief, Ben Bernanke, that the monetary authorities could simply drop piles of cash out of helicopters onto the country to be spent.  This money out of air (literally!) would lead to a huge boost in consumer demand and that would get sales, incomes and profits going.  This idea got more traction when Adair Turner, former head of the UK’s financial regulation authority, promoted it in his book Between Debt and the Devil, of course, in reality implemented by adding funds to people’s bank accounts.

This ‘solution’ is now being promoted as the last throw of the dice by the likes of Martin Wolf and Gavyn Davies, the Keynesian economic columnists of the UK’s Financial Times. We get a similar argument from the advisers to the Bernie Sanders US presidential campaign (and for that matter from advisers to the Corbyn-McDonnell Labour opposition in the UK).  Get money directly to the people and this will stimulate consumer demand and the economy will leap forward because there is plenty of pent-up demand waiting to be released.

This approach starts from the Keynesian premise that what is wrong with capitalist economies right now is a ‘chronic lack of demand’.  As Martin Wolf puts it in: “Behind this is a simple reality: the global savings glut — the tendency for desired savings to rise more than desired investment — is growing and so the “chronic demand deficiency syndrome” is worsening.”  The problem with capitalism right now is that “demand is also weak relative to a slowing growth of supply. At the world level, growth of labour supply and labour productivity has fallen sharply since the middle of the last decade. Lower growth of potential output itself weakens demand, because it lowers investment, always a crucial driver of spending in a capitalist economy.”

So weak demand causes lower investment causes lower growth.  But is that the order of causation?  In this blog I have argued consistently with evidence that the Keynesian premise is wrong: a lack of aggregate demand in a national economy or globally is the result of a slowdown or slump, not the cause.  The slump comes from a collapse in investment (in particular, business investment) and that happens when it is no longer profitable to invest.  Profit calls the tune, not ‘demand’.

Recently, fellow Marxist economist Alan Freeman presented a paper arguing that Marx and Keynes have much in common in their economic analysis of crises in capitalism and in the policy prescriptions (if not in their politics). Well, I beg to differ.  I don’t think the theoretical ideas of Keynes and Marx can be merged.  In this blog, I have emphasised the economic differences and in this paper here (contributions-of-keynes-and-marx)

The key point right now in the current global slowdown is the Keynesian analysis says that the problem is a lack of aggregate demand and increased government spending through the Keynesian demand multiplier can do the trick.  But the Marxian analysis says that it is profitability of investment that is key to capitalist-dominated economies and that it is the Marxist multiplier of profitability that can do the trick.  The problem with the latter is that profitability can only be restored through the destruction of value by stopping investment, liquidating old capital and making millions unemployed.  That is the contradiction of capitalism that Keynes did not recognise, along with all mainstream economics.

This is why the Sanders plan, admiral in its intention to provide jobs, incomes and public services, including healthcare and education, will not succeed under capitalism.  Sanders supporter, American economist, Gerald Friedman, caused a stir among mainstream economists, when he argued that: “Senator Sanders’s proposed policies would result in average annual output growth of 5.3% over the next decade, and average monthly job creation of close to 300,000. As a result, output in 2026 would be 37% higher than it would have been without the policies, and employment would be 16% higher.”

The idea is that boosting demand with government spending and raising wages significantly would deliver sustained economic growth that would pay for itself.  This idea has even gained support from former Federal Reserve regional director, Narayana Kocherlakota.  He reckons that US growth could easily be much higher than the mediocre rates projected for the coming years. He suggests the US economy could grow at 4-5 per cent a year over the next four years even if (total) productivity growth fails to recover “Under this alternative profile, [capital, labour and economic output] would [all] be (a little more than) 10% higher than is currently projected at the end of 2020.”

Achieving this may involve driving up wages and interest rates, he says, but only to “historically normal levels.” So give people more wages to spend more and demand will shoot up.  There is plenty of slack in the US economy: people without jobs and businesses ready to invest.  Indeed, higher wages would force businesses to invest in new labour-saving technology and drive up productivity growth, which is currently languishing at record lows.

Friedman’s arguments were subjected to a clinical critique by mainstream economists, Christine and David Romer,  romer-and-romer-evaluation-of-friedman1. Their main point was that boosting demand in the way Sanders-Friedman claim would not deliver the growth result because the capitalist economy did not have the ‘demand gap’ claimed and the ‘productive capacity’ of the US capitalist economy was too weak.  In other words, the US capitalist economy could only grow at 5% a year in real terms for the foreseeable future if it could expand investment and raise the productivity of labour over the next ten years.  And boosting demand won’t do that.  Of course, the Romer pair had no alternative to their critique of the Sanders proposals.

Anyway, government policymakers around the world are refusing to launch such fiscal spending programmes, even though infrastructure spending in Europe and the US is at 30-year lows and bridges, roads and railways are crumbling before our eyes.  According to the 2013 report card by the American Society of Civil Engineers, the US has serious infrastructure needs of more than $3.4 trillion through 2020, including $1.7 trillion for roads, bridges and transit; $736 billion for electricity and power grids; $391 billion for schools; $134 billion for airports; and $131 billion for waterways and related projects.  But federal investment in infrastructure has dropped by half during the past three decades, from 1 percent to 0.5 percent of GDP.

Why do governments refuse to introduce such policies in a meaningful way?  Well, it’s because government spending means more taxation on the corporate sector and/or on households, or it means more borrowing when public sector debt is at record highs.  And it means the encroachment of government into the capitalist sector just when profitability is turning down.

Monetarist solutions to the global slowdown have failed; Keynesian fiscal solutions are not being introduced and would not work in the long run anyway.  The only way out is another slump.

22 thoughts on “G20 and the mainstream solutions to a global slowdown

  1. Another great analysis, I appreciate your clarity in the chaotic din of neoclassicism and Keynesian nonsense.

    A question for you: you talk about the need to liquidate old capital: “profitability can only be restored through the destruction of value by stopping investment, liquidating old capital and making millions unemployed.”

    However, as I talked about in my own blog, traditional means of liquidating old capital through foreclosures, debt collection, using various options in derivative futures agreements, mergers and acquisitions, etc. are no longer the only ones possible in a post-Dodd-Frank world. And what better, what more abundant a source of capital than the “too big to fail” banks that fall under the Orderly Liquidation Authority of Article II.

    My question is this: assuming that the slowdown in investment will grow, if the government actually utilized OLA to liquidate a bank, would mass unemployment still result per se? I know using OLA is almost politically impossible, but I’m just curious if it is worth stating when inevitably OLA isn’t done and harm results.

  2. “So weak demand causes lower investment causes lower growth. But is that the order of causation?” Those words–the order of causation–are the mark of a totally undialectical concept of single causation. Every business cycle is characterized powerfully by unique circumstances, and those three aspects of its recession stage are entirely interdependent. Every ordering of them states an ongoing process every stage of which can see every one of them taking a “leading” role. But what is not part of the causal process is the long-term tendency in the pure Marxian model of capitalist development for the rate of profit to fall. Remember that in that model all surplus-value takes the form of profit-of-enterprise. But for a long time now the state-monopoly-capitalist economies have quite disregarded that model, Nowadays, the profit share of surplus-value is low and constantly falling relative to rent (including extractive rents) and interest (including “speculative” profits “guaranteed” by central-bank inflation of securities and raw-materials prices). In analyzing the ecological and financial contradictions of this global economy as it collapses into another recession without ever having emerged from its long-cycle depression, Herman Daly and Hyman Minsky are perhaps more relevant than Karl Marx.

    1. What you basically just said was that business cycles (something that repetitively occurs) cannot be understood in a general way because of the ungeneralizeable causal forces–or in other words Marxist is a pointless endeavor. Someone should reread Marx, his battles with Smith and Ricardo. Marx disproved the long-term TRPTD.
      I find it even more troubling that one could claim that capitalism itself has suspended the law of value and, necessarily with it, the labor theory of value. Thus it makes sense why you jettison Marx for bourgeois economists. Again, go back and read Marx. He clearly states that surplus value gets divided into rents, profits and interest rates, amongst other divisions. Yet you are the one that doesn’t have a theory for why there has been an explosion of credit and debt, or so-called financialization. Dialectically you can say whatever you want. Dialectics in Marx are not a replacement for causality, but a means of explaining causality–just like he does when he dialectically describes the tendency of the rate of profit to fall as a causal reason for crises to arise. Maybe you can dialectically describe how you managed to jettison the labor theory of value since now capitalism doesn’t care about production any more…

  3. Unfortunately, it seems that the only way out is not just “another slamp”, but the further expansion of the war that is already engulfing the world. Chaos spreads from Africa to the Middle East. The numbers of refugees globally have hit record heights. War by proxy and/or special ops is the order of the day, not to mention the NATO/Russia relations and the Sino/American crisis in the far east. If the peoples of the world and the international working class do not take action, i very much fear that the kind of “creative destruction” that awaits us will be far worse than just the economic manifestation of the phrase.

  4. “The slump comes from a collapse in investment (in particular, business investment) and that happens when it is no longer profitable to invest. Profit calls the tune, not ‘demand’.”

    But Marx says,

    “Firstly: Crises are usually preceded by a general inflation in prices of all articles of capitalist production. All of them therefore participate in the subsequent crash and at their former prices they cause a glut in the market. The market can absorb a larger volume of commodities at falling prices, at prices which have fallen below their cost-prices, than it could absorb at their former prices. The excess of commodities is always relative; in other words it is an excess at particular prices. The prices at which the commodities are then absorbed are ruinous for the producer or merchant.”

    And,

    “Here a great confusion: (1) This identity of supply, so that it is a demand measured by its own amount, is true only to the extent that it is exchange value = to a certain amount of objectified labour. To that extent it is the measure of its own demand — as far as value is concerned. But, as such a value, it first has to be realized through the exchange for money, and as object of exchange for money it depends (2) on its use value,but as use value it depends on the mass of needs present for it, the demand for it. But as use value it is absolutely not measured by the labour time objectified in it, but rather a measuring rod is applied to it which lies outside its nature as exchange value.”

    And,

    “The value supplied (but not yet realised) and the quantity of iron which is realised, do not correspond to each other. No grounds exist therefore for assuming that the possibility of selling a commodity at its value corresponds in any way to the quantity of the commodity I bring to market. For the buyer, my commodity exists, above all, as use-value. He buys it as such. But what he needs is a definite quantity of iron. His need for iron is just as little determined by the quantity produced by me as the value of my iron is commensurate with this quantity.
    It is true that the man who buys has in his possession merely the converted form of a commodity—money—i.e., the commodity in the form of exchange-value, and he can act as a buyer only because he or others have earlier acted as sellers of commodities which now exist in the form of money. This, however, is no reason why he should reconvert his money into my commodity or why his need for my commodity should be determined by the quantity of it that I have produced. Insofar as he wants to buy my commodity, he may want either a smaller quantity than I supply, or the entire quantity, but below its value. His demand does not have to correspond to my supply any more than the quantity I supply and the value at which I supply it are identical.”

    And,

    “The entire mass of commodities, i.e. , the total product, including the portion which replaces the constant and variable capital, and that representing surplus-value, must be sold. If this is not done, or done only in part, or only at prices below the prices of production, the labourer has been indeed exploited, but his exploitation is not realised as such for the capitalist, and this can be bound up with a total or partial failure to realise the surplus-value pressed out of him, indeed even with the partial or total loss of the capital. The conditions of direct exploitation, and those of realising it, are not identical. They diverge not only in place and time, but also logically. The first are only limited by the productive power of society, the latter by the proportional relation of the various branches of production and the consumer power of society. But this last-named is not determined either by the absolute productive power, or by the absolute consumer power, but by the consumer power based on antagonistic conditions of distribution, which reduce the consumption of the bulk of society to a minimum varying within more or less narrow limits. It is furthermore restricted by the tendency to accumulate, the drive to expand capital and produce surplus-value on an extended scale…The market must, therefore, be continually extended, so that its interrelations and the conditions regulating them assume more and more the form of a natural law working independently of the producer, and become ever more uncontrollable. This internal contradiction seeks to resolve itself through expansion of the outlying field of production. But the more productiveness develops, the more it finds itself at variance with the narrow basis on which the conditions of consumption rest. It is no contradiction at all on this self-contradictory basis that there should be an excess of capital simultaneously with a growing surplus of population. For while a combination of these two would, indeed, increase the mass of produced surplus-value, it would at the same time intensify the contradiction between the conditions under which this surplus-value is produced and those under which it is realised.”

    And

    “The ultimate reason for all real crises always remains the poverty and restricted consumption of the masses as opposed to the drive of capitalist production to develop the productive forces as though only the absolute consuming power of society constituted their limit.”

    And,

    “At a given moment, the supply of all commodities can be greater than the demand for all commodities, since the demand for the general commodity, money, exchange-value, is greater than the demand for all particular commodities, in other words the motive to turn the commodity into money, to realise its exchange-value, prevails over the motive to transform the commodity again into use-value.” (TOSV2 p 505)

    I think that you are making the same mistake that Marx criticised others for in these references, which is to conflate value and use value, the determinants of demand (use value), and of supply (value). As a consequence you end up with a version of Say’s Law, in which you assume that all that is important are the conditions of supply determined by value, and you then assume that demand automatically appears to soak up what has been produced at the resultant prices.

  5. Falling prices for raw materials cause a temporary disproportion as investments predicated on those high prices are cancelled, and the profits the yielded disappear. But then falling prices lower the organic composition of capital, raise the rate of profit and increase aggregate demand. How is this bad for the economy?
    Except of course, this is immaterial, as the recession’s coming this year, next year or the year after that, etc. Ad infinitum.

    1. Moreover Bill, as you so presciently pointed out about a year ago, the decline in oil prices, lowering input costs for production, was bound to be a veritable boon for consumers and industrialists alike. Remember that? And two or so years ago, you were telling us how the maritime transport industry too was booming. Remember?

      And you weren’t alone, were you? Not just Boffy, but even the head of the ECB, Mario Draghi was describing the decline in oil prices as a positive positive for the economy.

      But none of that matters, does it, as the economy’s underlying strength will assert itself this coming year, or next, or the year after that. Ad nauseum.

    2. Bill,

      Just a slight quibble. You say,

      “But then falling prices lower the organic composition of capital..”

      Actually they lower the value composition of capital, not the organic composition. In Capital I, Marx sets out that when he talks about the organic composition, he means the relation between the constant and variable capital primarily determined by the technical composition, i.e. the physical mass of material processed by a physical quantity of labour measured in value terms.

      “The composition of capital is to be understood in a two-fold sense. On the side of value, it is determined by the proportion in which it is divided into constant capital or value of the means of production, and variable capital or value of labour power, the sum total of wages. On the side of material, as it functions in the process of production, all capital is divided into means of production and living labour power. This latter composition is determined by the relation between the mass of the means of production employed, on the one hand, and the mass of labour necessary for their employment on the other. I call the former the value-composition, the latter the technical composition of capital.

      Between the two there is a strict correlation. To express this, I call the value composition of capital, in so far as it is determined by its technical composition and mirrors the changes of the latter, the organic composition of capital. Wherever I refer to the composition of capital, without further qualification, its organic composition is always understood.”

      Marx makes this distinction for several important reasons. Probably most importantly is that for Marx capital is the social relation between capital and wage labour. As he goes on to say, the expansion of capital is the expansion of this relation, and so the expansion of capital, is the expansion of the working-class. The primary driver of that, as he describes is not the value of capital employed, but the physical mass of capital employed, given any technical composition of capital. As Marx says workers have to do with the use value of the means of production they confront, not the value.

      Flowing from that, then is also the importance of distinguishing whether changes in the organic composition of capital flow from a rise in productivity, which changes the technical composition of capital, and thereby the organic composition as a result, or from a reduction in the value of different components of capital, as set out in Vol III, on the relation between the rate of surplus value and rate of profit, and in Chapter 6 on changes in those values directly on the rate of profit.

      If the technical composition rises as a result of rising productivity, then this may cause the occ to rise, creating the conditions for the law of falling profits to operate, depending upon the other effects it has on raising the rate of surplus value, reducing the values of constant capital and so on. For the reasons Marx sets out, it will lead to an expansion of capital, but the extent of the expansion will itself be affected by the very fact of the rise in productivity, which means that dependent on the structure of capital, at the particular time, it may result in absolutely more or less labour being employed.

      If the value of materials, which comprise the largest element of constant capital fall – or as Marx sets out in Chapter 6 if their market price falls, because of over supply – then the value composition of capital will fall, even though the technical composition, and so the organic composition has not changed. It may require as many workers to process 10000 kg of flax into yarn, after this change as it did before, but the price of the flax has fallen, so the value organic composition falls.

      That is important, as Marx sets out, because if the price of flax falls, spinners can buy more of it, to spin into yarn. But, if the technical composition has not changed, this increase in the amount of flax to be spun, requires the same increase in the employment of spinners as before. The fall in the value of the constant capital, creating a release of capital, allows more means of production and labour-power to be employed, creating an expansion of capital, of surplus value, and of the rate of profit.

      As Marx puts it,

      “Other conditions being equal, the rate of profit, therefore, falls and rises inversely to the price of raw material. This shows, among other things, how important the low price of raw material is for industrial countries, even if fluctuations in the price of raw materials are not accompanied by variations in the sales sphere of the product, and thus quite aside from the relation of demand to supply.”

    3. “Moreover Bill, as you so presciently pointed out about a year ago, the decline in oil prices, lowering input costs for production,”

      In some nations the domestic consumer subsidises business UK is a prime example). The problem with this is that a fall in oil prices helps somewhat the domestic consumer but not much the business! And it is infamous that prices are sticky coming down but very responsive when going up! So the middle men see the biggest benefit of all! being a finite resource oil is bound to increase in price again and the domestic consumer will once again subsidise business to a large extent.

      Regarding investment decisions, I think most companies will employee people to look at expected future cost, expected future sales, expected future profit, and any other ratio you can think of. After all we are in the era of big data and cloud computing.

      Bill may think forecasting is a wild goose chase but that doesn’t stop every company on Earth doing it and being obsessed by it. Most companies will have instigated certain measures to assume forecasts become real. Risk planning for example.

      If demand was the heart of every crises then the old William Beveridge formula of socialization of demand without the socialization of production would suffice. My understanding of Marx is that crises are the mechanism to restore ‘equilibrium’ to capital accumulation. Not simply some response to a demand shock.

      1. When it comes to forecasting, Marxists have nothing to gloat about when compared to big corporations and institutions…

      2. “Marxists have nothing to gloat about when compared to big corporations and institutions”

        Institutions and corporations only really forecast their immediate environment and they are good at this until something really unexpected occurs, Marxists are analyzing the system as a whole. I would argue Marxists are not really forecasting but they do make predictions – these are different things. This is one of the areas where Bill jefferies gets confused.

        The biggest indicator of how well big capitalists forecast is the market value. Markets have never predicted a crisis but they certainly let you know when one has arrived.

Leave a comment

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.