Brexit, TTIP and TTP

One of the ironies of the Brexit vote by the British people (more exactly, the English and the Welsh as the Scots voted to remain), is that the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership, otherwise known as TTIP, has been crippled, possibly killed.  It looks as though any potential trade agreement with the US will be ‘parked’ by the EU Commission until Britain’s Article 50 (Brexit) negotiations have been completed.  Washington is also being forced to put a hold on TTIP because Britain represents 16% of the EU market. Until Britain’s relationship with the EU is finalised, there is no way to assess the nature and scale of the reduction in the EU’s market, making it impossible to value.

There is now a possibility that the deal will never be concluded.

Anyway, with Article 50 unlikely to be invoked very quickly by the new Conservative government under Theresa May, there would seem to be insufficient time to conclude the negotiations before the end of the year, and many in Brussels now want to focus on obtaining the ‘right Brexit’ terms, pushing TTIP down the list of priorities. And with next year’s elections in France, Germany, and Holland, EU leaders will try to avoid another weapon to be used by ‘populist’ parties who see TTIP as another attempt to impose measures of ‘globalisation’ on nation states..

There has been much coverage about how TTIP, if implemented, will impose serious restrictions on the ability of democratic governments to carry out the wishes of their electorates.  TTIP and its baby sister, CETA, a similar trade deal that the EU has negotiated with Canada, enable corporations to sue governments in secret commercial Investor State Dispute Settlement (ISDS) courts. This right of litigation exposes governments to lawsuits for any policy-induced losses suffered by a corporation.  Governments are exposed to corporate action through ISDS courts for up to 20 years.

But aside from the issue of democratic governments being blocked and sued under these international trade treaties, there is the question of whether international trade agreements, bilateral or multilateral, are beneficial to labour or to capital.  The specifically economic base of such a conception is that has been known since the first sentence of the first chapter of the founding work of scientific economics, Adam Smith’s The Wealth of Nationsthat: ‘The greatest improvement in the productive powers of labour… have been the effects of the division of labour.’

Mainstream economists are convinced that ‘free trade’ is beneficial to all.  As Keynesian Paul Krugman put it: “The great majority of economists would argue that the gains from reducing trade protection still exceed the losses. However, it has become more important than before to make sure that the gains from international trade are widely spread.”  How the latter is to be done is not explained.  Greg Mankiw, the right of centre mainstream economist who reckons that inequality of income is justified, is more honest: “will trade make everyone better off? Probably not. In practice, compensation for the losers from international trade is rare. Without such compensation, opening up to international trade is a policy that expands the size of the economic pie, while perhaps leaving some participants in the economy with a smaller slice.”

The idea that ‘free trade’ is beneficial to all countries and to all classes is a ‘sacred tenet’ of mainstream economics.  In his new book, Capitalism, Anwar Shaikh (Chapter 11), analyses in detail the fallacious proposition that if each country concentrated on producing goods or services where it has a ‘comparative advantage’ over others (so its ‘comparative costs’ were lower), then all would benefit.  Trading between countries would balance and wages and employment would be maximised.

Shaikh shows that this is not only demonstrably untrue (countries run huge trade deficits and surpluses for long periods; have recurring currency crises; and workers lose jobs from competition from abroad without getting new ones from more competitive sectors).  Shaikh also explains why: namely that it is not comparative advantage or costs that drives trade, but the absolute costs.  If Chinese labour costs are much lower than American companies’ labour costs in any market, then China will gain market share, even if America has some so-called ‘comparative advantage’. What really decides is the productivity level and growth in an economy and the cost of labour: “free trade will lead to persistent trade surpluses for countries whose capitals have lower costs and persistent trade deficits for those whose capital has higher costs”. (Shaikh p 514).

In the US, the big losers from the current wave of globalization have been the working-class, as Branko Milanovic of the City University of New York details in his new book, Global Inequality. Jobs will go as more efficient economies take trade share from the less efficient and with open markets (no tariffs and special restriction or quotas).

And of course, in the TTIP and TTP (Trans Pacific) deals, nothing is done to help those who lose employment as a result. For example, the US Trade Adjustment Assistance (TAA) program has a budget of about $664 million, or roughly 0.004 percent of GDP; military and security spending used to preserve imperialist markets for the US costs 4000 times more!   Instead, just one dollar of every $25,000 in income generated by the United States goes to help people here who have been hurt by globalization.  They don’t receive the cash directly; they just have to hope that the program — which offers retooling, retraining, and relocation, among other services — will aid their transition to new jobs.

In reality, these trade agreements like the TTIP and its pacific twin, TTP (already signed but not confirmed by national governments) are aimed to improve the interest of the multinationals in world markets.  The trade discussions are really a battle between the stronger and the weaker capitalist economies over whose companies get the best deal.  This is the essence of ‘regional’ deals that have replaced the failed and defunct global deals that the World Trade Organisation (WTO) has tried to achieve over the past 20 years..

In the case of the TTP, the agreement is specifically designed by the US and Japan to squeeze the ability of Chinese companies to build market share in Asia.  The real character of the US TPP becomes clear immediately the fundamental economic data for its 12 intended signatory countries is examined. The potential signatories are dominated by the G7 economies of the US, Japan, and Canada. These, together with Australia, constitute 90% of the GDP of potential signatories. Participating developing economies – Mexico, Malaysia, Chile, Vietnam and Peru – make up only 8%.

In effect, the TTIP and TTP are really an attempt by the US to stop the decline in global market share at others expense, and also to counteract weakening economic growth and profitability at home. In 1985 economies in the proposed TPP countries accounted for 54% of world GDP; by 2014 this had dropped to 36%. From 1984-2014 the US share of world GDP fell from 34% to 23%, at current exchange rates. In the same period the US share of world merchandise trade dropped from 15% to 11%. So the TPP is not some great free trade beneficence but really an agreement by a group of advanced economies, with a ‘fringe’ of developing countries, whose share in world GDP has been significantly declining to keep others out.

TTP

Indeed, it is very far away from the sacred idea of ‘free trade’.  As US economist Jeffrey Sachs noted of these TPP provisions: ‘Their common denominator is that they enshrine the power of corporate capital above all other parts of society, including… even governments… The most egregious parts of the agreement are the exorbitant investor powers implicit in the Investor-State Dispute Settlement system as well as the unjustified expansion of copyright and patent coverage. We’ve seen this show before. Corporations are already using ISDS provisions in existing trade and investment agreements to harass governments in order to frustrate regulations and judicial decisions that negatively impact the companies’ interests. The system proposed in the TPP is a dangerous and unnecessary… blow to the judicial systems of all the signatory countries.’

The TPP also gives legal protection to software companies, overwhelmingly US, to essentially spy on signatory states. Article 14.17 states: ‘No Party shall require the transfer of, or access to, source code of software owned by a person of another Party, as a condition for the import, distribution, sale or use of such software, or of products containing such software, in its territory.’ While it is stated this does not apply to ‘critical infrastructure’ it does not exclude banks, commercial companies etc.  In short, the conception of the TPP is not to maximise prosperity for the Asia-Pacific Region but to enshrine US supremacy.   The TTIP does the same for the US in the European arena.

These deals are being negotiated in an environment where world trade is stagnating at best.  Since the end of the Great Recession, world trade has grown no faster than the sluggish growth in world output – and that is unprecedented, in the post-war period, trade has always grown faster than output.  It is another indicator that we are in a long depression and not a normal boom and slump.

Global trade

So it would appear that ‘globalisation’ is stuttering and trade is offering no way out for capitalist economies in depression or stagnation.

Trade plateau

And that is not a rosy scenario for the British negotiators of a new trade deals outside the European Union.

5 thoughts on “Brexit, TTIP and TTP

  1. In short: this is not about trade but acquiring international property rights, protecting them and dominating others – plus ensuring that the lowest denominator in social and environmental protection that the dominating power holds will be respected. Interesting though that the US now seems to forget its important interests in China. Thirdly: already Adam Smith knew that Britain only started promoting free trade when she had eliminated the competition via the Navigation Acts. So good luck to the Brexit negotiators. With the ilk of David Davies who seems to have a chronic grinning problem and Boorish Johnson (pun intended) on the sidelines in the international negotiations, Theresa may stall indefinitely.

  2. Great article!

    I wonder how you nailed it here “In short, the conception of the TPP is not to maximise prosperity for the Asia-Pacific Region but to enshrine US supremacy.” and you “miss” it here with the TTIP/CETA?

    In 1957 we had the Rome Treaty. In 2007 we had the Lisbon Treaty. Circle closed.

    The TTIP/CETA is just the “equivalent”of Rome Treaty for the running the world from the Arctic. Yes, somewhere on the process Russia will be in! However, the show will be guided by the empire of course.

    The backbone for that exists already: NATO and the regarding the finance the heads and tails producers you have them already in the institutions of the FED and ECB.
    A little note here, it might be the blockchain might mess everything including ALL economics theories.

    For the organizations who run the show what is keeping for them is how to control the 1,5 billion persons which have the perception who owns something. The other 5,7 billion persons living with less than 10 USD/day are absolutely non-existing for them. For purpose of control they will find ways of surviving to the dramatic climate change or even nuclear accident which will happen. Some of the 1,5 billion will be there happily to help them.

    The others ones according to their view can die. The important is that when they are alive they do not transmit diseases in large scale.

  3. Hi Mr. Roberts, I’m constantly trying to dredge through the sea of convoluted information that’s reported each day to find the most important sources regarding war, the environment, economics, etc. Usually what I look for are large, comprehensive reports from supranational organizations and/or credible think tanks. The “Global Trade Plateaus” by Evenett & Fritz that you sourced in this blog post is a perfect example of the type of documents I’m looking for. I was wondering if you’ve created a list of sources/bookmarks regarding global economics that you might be willing to forward to me? It might seem like an odd question, but it takes years to build up a body of sources to inform one’s worldview and keep up with current events (which is so much more tasking than it was 100, 200 years ago), and though I have quite a few of my own, I’m always struggling to find the heart of the matter, the origin of the information that’s reported. So please, if you have any recommendations or a body of sources you’d be willing to share with a fellow Marxist, I would be eternally grateful and productive with them.

    Your long time subscriber, Gabriel

    On Thu, Jul 14, 2016 at 2:39 AM, Michael Roberts Blog wrote:

    > michael roberts posted: “One of the ironies of the Brexit vote by the > British people (more exactly, the English and the Welsh as the Scots voted > to remain), is that the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership, > otherwise known as TTIP, has been crippled, possibly killed. I” >

  4. “In effect, the TTIP and TTP are really an attempt by the US to stop the decline in global market share at others expense, and also to counteract weakening economic growth and profitability at home”.

    IOW, what we have is the diametric opposite of “free trade”: Neo-mercantilism. And who is at the center of all these neo-mercantile cartel deals? The USA. And what state still rests upon its 230 year old “pre-capitalist”, but bourgeois MERCANTILE slave-owning constitution, sans now the actual slavery? The USA. And what does that tell us about the historical character of US capitalism?

    Trick question, over to you.

  5. “The TPP also gives legal protection to software companies, overwhelmingly US, to essentially spy on signatory states. Article 14.17 states: ‘No Party shall require the transfer of, or access to, source code of software…'” — Okay, hiding source code allows the U.S. to plant spy modules in software. On the other hand, showing the source code gives competitors a free ride on the cost of developing it. How can capitalists resolve that one?

Leave a comment

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.