Going the last mile

Headline inflation rates in the major economies have nearly halved since they peaked back in 2022.  Average consumer price growth across the advanced capitalist economies has dropped from more than 7% in 2022 to 4.6% in 2023, according to the IMF.

The reason for the acceleration of consumer price inflation from 2020-2022 has now been well established.  It was caused by a sharp fall in the supply of basic commodities and intermediate products which drove up prices of these suddenly scarce goods.  This was compounded by a breakdown in the global supply chain of goods transported and trade internationally.

The inflationary spiral from the end of the pandemic slump in 2020 to the peak in 2022 was not the result of ‘excessive demand’ caused by too much government spending or wage increases driving up costs for companies.  Study after study has shown that it was supply issues not wage demands that generated the price rises (an average rise of 20% over two years).  Indeed, if anything, it was excessive profit rises that contributed as companies with any ‘market power’ ie a monopolistic position took advantage of rising input costs to raise their ‘mark-ups’.  This was particularly the case from the energy and food majors which control the pricing in those markets.

And yet, central bankers continue to insist that inflation rates well above their policy target of 2% a year were caused by ‘too much’ demand or ‘excessive’ wage rises.  They have to say this because it is their raison d’etre.  Central banks are here to manipulate interest rates and money supply, supposedly in order to ‘control’ inflation and the economy.  They rest their policies on the monetarist theory that it is money supply growth and the cost of borrowing (interest rates) that control price inflation.  But the experience of the post-pandemic inflationary ‘shock’ exposed (yet again) the nonsense of monetarism.

Do we need to control inflation?  For workers, the answer is clearly, yes; because no inflation and even deflation means that their weekly or monthly pay checks are worth the same and any increase would mean better living standards.  But that is not the same for companies.  They like and want some ‘moderate’ inflation as it allows room to preserve profitability when costs of production rise or wage rises offer more demand.  That’s why central banks do not have a target of zero inflation, but instead something like 2% a year. 

But setting a target of 2% a year is really admitting that central banks cannot control price inflation.  Indeed, if we look at the history of monetary policy and its ability to achieve the (arbitrarily fixed) inflation target of 2% a year in the major advanced capitalist economies, it has been a total failure.   Take the ECB’s record.  In the 25 years of the existence of the euro, the ECB has only got close to achieving the 2% target once, in 2007.  In every other year, inflation has been either well above 2% or well below. 

Just by chance the 25-year average inflation rate is 2%, but as the chart below shows, there was a multi-year streak of undershooting the 2% from the end of 2013 (with an annual average inflation at just 0.7% to 2020, then the current overshoot (the annual average inflation since end-2020 has been 5.7%).  And before 2013, the inflation rate was always well above target, despite hiking interest rates and keeping money supply growth down.  In the 2010s, despite quantitative easing (monetary injections) and low and even zero interest rates, inflation did not reach 2% a year.  Overall, the inflation rate had a standard deviation from the 2% annual target of 1.8 times.

It is the same story with the US Fed.  The Fed was close to its target in only two years out of the last 24, and with a standard deviation of 1.2 times.  The Fed failed to keep inflation down to 2% in the 2000s and failed to get inflation up to 2% in the 2010s.  Neither tight monetary policy worked in the 2000s, nor did ‘loose’ monetary policy work in the 2010s.

And when it comes to the Bank of Japan, it totally failed to get inflation up to 2% a year until the recent inflationary shock, despite zero interest rates and massive quantitative easing (bond purchases). 

What the BoJ record confirms is that it is activity in the ‘real’ economy and the decisions of banks and companies regarding their profits (including whether to ‘hoard’ money) that decides inflation, not central bank monetary policy.

Despite the futility of their policies, central banks have ploughed on with trying to control inflation in the last two years by raising interest rates and tightening money supply.  Now they are claiming their policies are why inflation rates have dropped in the last year and are still falling (for now).  And yet it is clear that it is the sharp fallback in energy and food prices and prices for various intermediate products that has driven average inflation down. 

At the same time, global supply chain pressures have been reduced. 

New York Fed global supply chain pressure index (GSCPI).

Central bank monetary policy has had little to do with any of this. 

Isabel Schnabel is the most hawkish member of the ECB’s six-person executive board. The German economist has become one of the most influential voices on eurozone monetary policy.  She continues to argue that monetary policy has been effective in controlling inflation.  “Monetary policy was and remains essential to bring inflation down. If you look around, you see signs of monetary policy transmission everywhere. Just look at the tightening of financing conditions and the sharp deceleration of bank lending. Look at the decline of housing investments or at weak construction activity. And importantly, look at the broadly anchored inflation expectations in the wake of the largest inflation shock we have experienced in decades.”

Even Schnabel has to admit that, “It’s true, of course, that part of the decline in inflation reflects the reversal of supply-side shocks.” (only ‘part’?). But she continues, “monetary policy has been instrumental in slowing the pass-through of higher costs to consumer prices and in containing second-round effects.”  By ‘second round effects’, she means inflation expectations.

But most of these signs are of tightening monetary policies with no causal connection to inflation.  The claim that inflation was curbed by central banks ‘anchoring inflation expectations’ is really a psychological theory of inflation.  Inflation expectations by consumers and companies only vary because of what is actually happening to prices.  Inflation expectations have fallen because price inflation has slowed.

According to Schnabel, now the war against inflation was “at a critical phase where the calibration and transmission of monetary policy become especially important because it is all about containing the second-round effects.”  This was what she has called “the last mile” in the battle to get inflation down to 2% a year. 

And what is the difficulty here?  Yet again, it is not supply issues or even profit mark-ups, but “the strong growth in nominal wages as employees are trying to catch up on their lost income.”.  For Schnabel, it’s wage demands that are stopping inflation from falling further.

But Schnabel has to admit that if productivity growth (output per worker) were rising too, then wage costs per unit of output would not rise and profits would be secure.  Unfortunately, for corporate profits, “we’ve seen a worrying decline in productivity” so “the combination of the strong rise in nominal wages and the drop in productivity has led to a historically high growth in unit labour costs.” 

And indeed, there is a strong inverse correlation (0.45) between productivity growth and inflation rates over the last two decades.

Without sufficient productivity growth (more exploitation of labour), this could drive down profitability unless wage demands are curbed.  “How are firms going to react? Will they be able to pass through higher unit labour costs to consumer prices?”, worries Schnabel.  This is where central bank monetary policy comes in, namely to curb spending and investment by raising the cost of borrowing, she argues.

Schnabel is worried that the inflation beast has not been tamed yet and so high interest rates must be sustained.  She refers to an IMF study that claims to show that when interest rates are kept high until the pips of the economic orange squeak, this not only stops inflation coming back, but also eventually gets the economy going quicker afterwards.  This is the Volcker policy of the late 1970s in the US.  Volcker was the Fed chief then and to ‘cure’ the economy from inflation he maintained high interest rates until the US economy dropped into a slump.  Inflation then subsided but along with the economy and jobs.  But this ‘cleansed’ the economy supposedly for faster growth later in the 1980s.

But the cleansing solution comes at a price (sic). The IMF report’s key finding is that the successful resolution of inflation shocks was associated with more substantial monetary policy tightening.  “But those that resolved inflation with high interest rates experienced a larger decline in GDP growth than those that did not.” (IMF).

The problem with Schnabel’s monetarist theory is that it does not hold with the reality of capitalist production.  Within this theory is the neoclassical concept of an ‘equilibrium rate of interest’ called R*, which is the interest rate level that supposedly keeps inflation to the set target, but also avoids unemployment and a slump.  Schnabel: “The problem is it cannot be estimated with any confidence, which means that it is extremely hard to operationalize …. What we really care about is the short-run R-star, because it is relevant to determine whether our interest rates are restrictive or accommodative. The problem is we don’t know where it is precisely.” (!)

Indeed, as Minneapolis Fed President Neel Kashkari recently explained, “The concept of a neutral stance of monetary policy is critical to assessing where policy is now and what pressure it is having on the economy. While we cannot directly observe neutral, economists have models to estimate it, which are imperfect even under normal economic circumstances. Our various workhorse models for the economy have struggled to explain and forecast the pandemic and post-pandemic periods given the extraordinary changes and disruptions the economy has experienced.  So I also look to measures of economic activity for signals to try to evaluate the stance of policy. In other words, the monetarist theory cannot be applied to reality and the reality is that economic activity drives inflation and money circulation, not vice versa.

Schnabel recognizes the past failure of monetarist policies.  “One is the period after the launch of the ECB’s asset purchase programme in 2015. That was a time when a lot of central bank reserves — base money — were created. But we did not succeed in lifting the economy out of the low-inflation environment. Why was that?” The reason was that “the balance sheets of banks, firms, households and governments were relatively weak. You remember, after the global financial crisis and the euro area sovereign debt crisis, there was little willingness to grant loans and to invest. Inflation did not come back as much as the ECB would have hoped.” Exactly. 

It was the state of the real economy, in particular profitability of capital and the low demand for credit to invest, not the price of money, not the mythical R*, that drove the economy.  The ECB was ‘pushing on a string’, to use Keynes’ phrase, and getting nowhere in reaching its arbitrary 2% inflation target.  Schnabel again: “the ECB’s asset purchases before the pandemic were not as successful in bringing inflation back to our target as we would have hoped, because their effectiveness depends on the economic environment.”

Indeed.  The truth is that central banks have little or no influence over the investment decision of companies – it’s the profitability of investment that matters, and from that, flows how much inflation emerges in an economy.  Given that profitability of capital currently remains low, investment growth is weak and productivity is not recovering much, this suggests that Schnabel’s ‘last mile’ is more like a horizon that she will never reach.

17 thoughts on “Going the last mile

  1. What distinguishes Marxists is that they avoid one-sided analyses opting instead for all-sided analyses. Even neglecting a single side, or assumption, leads to partial conclusions. The only side we can eliminate with certainty is that inflation was not caused by wage rises.

    However, when we examine what happened to prices and profits, the picture is more complicated. According to NIPA Table 1.10 (line 8) Covid subsidies to business amounted to between $1.1 trillion and $1.2 Trillion during the three years 2020 and 2022. (BEA Interactive Data Application) Around 80% of this would have found its way to non-financial corporations. Thus over the three years, corporate profits were boosted by $0.9 trillion. Then there was the cumulative 17% in excess price rises based on durable and non-durable goods prices. Taking the values found in NIPA Table 1.14, line 19 – Net Value Added – that added a further $1.5 trillion over three years. When added to subsidies this was in the range of $2.4 to $2.5 trillion over the three years. That was almost 50% of the total $5.1 trillion in Covid Assistance. Considering that pre-tax profit during this time amounted to $8.5 trillion (line 32) the profits attributed to non-value production, aka covid funds, amounted to 30% of all profits.

    Here I part company with Michael. Of course supply side disruptions and obstructions played a major role in driving up prices. Another way of saying this is that the amount of value produced during this time was reduced. On the demand side however, Covid funds, particularly in the USA, did drive up demand. We just have to view this breathtaking graph of M1 (money supply) https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/M1SL to see this is so.

    It is a matter of fact that prices regularly diverge from values in the general sense within a capitalist society. Marx himself pointed to the business or industrial cycle as he called it, where prices fall below values in the down-phases only to rise above values in the up-phases particularly towards the climax of the cycle when credit is rampant. The confusion here has to do with a Keynesian misconception, namely that pushing money towards the capitalists is like pushing on the end of a piece of string. But workers are not capitalists who have more money than brains, workers don’t have the option of hoarding or spending, particularly during a pandemic. They spent the money they received in assistance, driving up demand, this was to be expected.

    Turning to the physiognomy of money, the result was that the money supply was no longer based primarily on unspent revenues, that is legacy value, value previously produced, but had been diluted by Covid Funds which were not value based but debt based. Thus the demand side was no longer regulated by value while the supply side continued to be, and the result was the debauching of money and hence inflation. The problem with Covid money as opposed to bank money is that the former is permanent money while the latter is temporary because it has to be paid back. It was this permanency which explains why M1 remained elevated long after the Covid funds ended which in turn helps explain the resilience in consumer spending up to Q3 2023 despite higher interest rates.

  2. Isabel Schnabel is part of the creme de la creme of the intellectuals in the Humanities area Europe can offer for the public sector. She’s the personification of the intellectual decline of the West, a process that started with Marx’s death.

    The degeneration is very clear: you see, guys, according to Schnabel, if you “look around”, then Monetarism (here used as the umbrella term for her ideology) is correct. But what if don’t “look around”? Does Monetarism stops being true; or does only the monetarists have the capacity to “look around”? Are we, the non-monetarists, literally blind and deaf, literally incapable of observation?

    But then, even if we “look around”, Monetarism is merely and approximation: it only explains “part of the decline”; it “it cannot” estimate “with any confidence”; it thinks to be “extremely hard to operationalize”; it only “cares about” but, even on this “caring” they “don’t know where it is precisely”.

    Well, maybe then, if Ms. Schnabel starts to “look around”, she may be able to “know where it is precisely” “with any confidence”.

    –//–

    It’s funny how the post-Cold War era made the economists the dominant class of intellectuals of the Humanities, to the point they became the last guardians of the End of History.

    All the other areas of Humanities that flourished during the euphoria of the End of History era (pre-history 1979-1991; era proper: 1992-2008; late stage (latency of fall): 2009-2016) have already fallen: Postmodernism, Postcolonialism, Sociology, (neo)Anthropology etc. etc. All of them have already become dust of History, but Economics has become its last guardian, resisting postmodern reforms during the 1980s-1990s, essentially unchanged since the great Neoclassical unification of the first half of the past century. It became something like the Senate was for the Roman Empire: the last bastion of Roman paganism, remaining so until its extinction, after the fall of the Roman Empire in the West. Somethings, indeed, do ossify and never change.

    We still live — and will continue to live for the foreseeable future — in the era of Marx.

  3. Thank you for this piece, which collects some information new to me, and I would hardly argue with your basic thesis.. A couple of questions.

    1. The chart labelled “Figure 12  sources of price inflation” does not appear in your article of  27April23 which you link to at the start of that paragraph – 

    The reason for the acceleration of consumer price inflation from 2020-2022 has now been well established.  It was caused by a sharp fall in the supply of basic commodities and intermediate products which drove up prices of these suddenly scarce goods.  This was compounded by a breakdown in the global supply chain of goods transported and trade internationally

    So where does Figure 12 come from, please ?

    And incidentally what is v/u ?

    2.  The chart “US annual productivity growth and inflation (%), 1948-2023 shows, you suggest, “a strong inverse correlation (0.45) between productivity growth and inflation rates over the last two decades.” A correlation of 0.45 is not “strong”; and the line, presumably regression, shown on the chart ignores the exteme scattering of the data. The first thing to say about this data is that there is a very strong central tendency for productivity growth around 2%, broadly between 1 and 3. There may in addition be a downward tendency. for low inflation to be associated with higher productivity growth: but in view of the difficulties in measuring productivity and in attributing its growth / decline to a particular period, I would not put much weight on it – and as the inflation data is, I imagine CPI, it may be only loosely connected with productivity anyway. But the use of a regression to justify conclusions about tendencies on such slight correlation is a fault too many  economists are prone to. (I am, as you will be aware, no economist, but I do know a little about statistics.)

    Since this chart has on effect on your central argument, that Schanbel is a ninny or worse, it seems a pity to include it.

    3. You say at the end that “the profitability ofcapital remains low” but profits generally rebounded after the pandemic; you have made the point that companies have pushed up profits boosting inflation; and sources such as FRED [https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/CP/] or the Bureau of Economic Affairs [https://www.bea.gov/data/income-saving/corporate-profits] show profits in the USA increasing (I accept that there are problems with e.g. China, but equally they do not curretnly have an inflation problem). Am I missing  some definition here ?

    1. I have always maintained the holy grail of Central Bank inflation, 2%, was actually based on the average annual productivity figure of 2%, meaning that any wage rise under 4% meant the capitalists profiting from productivity. Other than that I agree with you, the correlations in the article are weak.

      1. It makes sense to separate consumer price inflation and asset price inflation. They’re pretty much separate economies. Central bank stimulants don’t really effect consumer prices, but they surely do effect property and stock market prices on short-mid term.

    2. @ardj

      I’m the most clueless of dilettantes here, so take my words with a cartload of salt.

      Apropos of your third point, I’d say that Dr Roberts often makes a distinction, as all Marxists I know do, between the mass and the rate of profits, since there’s a temporal lag from changes in the latter to changes in the former. Besides that, I think he means that profitability remains low because the post-pandemic rebound hasn’t overall changed the secular trend of profitability, or even the trend since 2008. Assuming you’re new here, I’d suggest you read the extensive posts Dr Roberts has made on the rate of profit in select countries or in the world.

      In the interest of completeness, I’ll add that while I’m convinced by the Marxian argument, this is hardly the case of all people who comment here.

      There are people like Dr Jack Rasmus who think there are too many fudge factors in the calculation of the profit rate for any value calculated based on any set of assumptions to be useful in modelling crises or economic trends as whole, even if we agree that the TRPF is real. These fudge factors, he argues, are baked into accounting standards of large companies and it’s impossible to compile the “true” rate of profit.

      Then there are people who think the profit rate can be calculated, but Dr Roberts and others are doing it wrong by choosing wrong assumptions. That’s the case of Dr Bill Jefferies, who purports to show that a better choice of assumptions leads to the conclusion that in the US the RoP has been rising. You can read a summary of the arguments here: https://thenextrecession.wordpress.com/2023/11/19/hm-2023-value-profit-technology-and-value-again/.

      1. @DGE

        Many thanks – dilettante myself as no economist, not a convinced Marxist, and, though not exactly new, only an occasional reader. I was aware of some of Dr Roberts’ exegesis of profits – probably a good idea to read more. I own that I share the doubts you point to about the calculation of profit – both how it can be manipulated and measurement problems. You may well be right suggesting the profits remaining low refers to the secular trend, and I would not argue with that as a claim. An unqualified thank you for the references.

      2. @ardj

        Like I said, I think the TRPF can be derived from first principles, and as such is fundamental to a capitalist economy. Right now, I think disbelieving it would be like disbelieving gravity. I also believe it’s the best way to explain crises.

        Whether it’s useful to forecast crises is another matter. But that is probably not a fault of the theory, but of the difficulty in measuring the rate of profit. Some people even think that the difficulty is a feature, not a bug.

        In general, I think different standards of accounting cannot revert a trend, only accentuate or alleviate it. So I don’t buy Dr Rasmus’ objections. If the trend is there, it should appear in the data: the Sun won’t rise in the West if we measure the length of the day with badly calibrated clocks.

        Dr Jefferies’ are another matter. I’ve read Dr Roberts’ rebuttal (linked in the reference I gave you), and it sounded cogent to me, especially his pointing out that if the RoP were rising, companies would behave differently from what they’re actually doing. But I find it worrisome if a researcher in good faith can use assumptions that will yield an opposite result: that would mean the fudge factors are actually strong enough to make the whole exercise pointless. But like I said, I think Dr Jefferies’ results are an outlier disconnected from reality.

        And like Dr Brian Green says, mainstream economists pretend that profits aren’t all that important for modelling investment and policymaking, but if you look at corporate white papers and Fed literature, you see that capitalists do put profit foremost among factors guiding their decisions – it’s just that it’s not okay to admit to it.

        Still, some like vk have pointed out that being at the centre of the capitalist system, it’s possible for the US to prosper by cannibalising its satellites, so I wouldn’t be surprised if it turned out that Dr Jefferies is right in the case of the US. Recent news on the collapse of Germany’s industry, due to energy prices engendered by the US meddling in Ukraine and Russia and roping the EU into the whole affair, suggest to me that vk may be right and the US is thriving off the decline of other developed capitalist countries at this point.

        All very interesting, and under-researched, I think.

  4. Apropos of UCBP’s comment I was, coincidentally, just reading Costas Lapavitsis on Marx and the Banking School:

    ”…regular and developed commodity exchange also poses the requirement that the ‘independent form of value’ should intervene in the market from without as it were. Circumstances regularly appear in which the the ‘universal equivalent’ is called upon to confront exchange as an external social force; specifically, agents have to be able to buy and sell at all times, deferred payments have to be completed, international transactions have to be settled”

    I know a lot of people who could not have made rent etc without the Covid payments.

    Unlike credit money, which is extinguished on repayment, the various central bank interventions were, if I may co-opt CL’s reading, “money’s third function…(money) as money” preserving the other functions. The sort of temporary inflation UCBP attributes in part to the one-time but permanent cash injection might, from this point of view, seem preferable to central bankers than a general collapse of regular and developed exchange.

    that doesn’t of course mean they won’t want to impose the cost of inflation on the workers…

    Anyway, grist for the commenting mill.

    1. Costas Lapavitsas’ is wrong (in this quote): the market (exchange) is a manifestation of value (as an “independent existence”), not a external institution to it. Labor as abstract value is only possible because there is the separation of circulation from production, where production is directed to exchange (in the free market; circulation). In other words, labor can only ever manifest as value in a situation where the “market” is already given. Value (alienation) is “external” to labor, not to the “market”. To claim value can “intervenes”, “confronts” in the market is akin to claim atmospheric oxygen “intervenes” and/or “confronts” the human body’s cells because it eventually destroys (oxidizes) our DNA.

      This may seen as a cheap philosophical differentiation or hair splitting, but it is crucial, because Lapavitsas then concludes that, because of this estrangement between value and exchange/market, capitalism is forced to “buy and sell at all times”, i.e. it is not capitalism’s fault that it is so voracious, but merely the act of probably the central banks and the big banks and other financial institutions (I assume they are in another part of the quoted paragraph) that is disrupting it; when, in fact, we know that capitalism must to continue to “buy and sell at all times” because of its very existence M – C – M’, and not because of an alleged “independent form [from the market] of value”.

      –//–

      Money in capitalism is always the three functions at the same time. There is no segregation between them: a central bank cannot issue money e.g. only as a means of payment and not as unity of accountancy and reserve of value. It is literally impossible.

      If you have a literal Benjamin in your hands, you cannot pretend it only serves as, for example, unity of accountancy. It is the three functions at the same time, and it must be, otherwise capitalism would be impossible to exist in the real world.

      There is no concept of “make believe” in Marx’s theory. What is subjective is concretely subjective. What is social is concretely social. Obviously, this remains true for fictitious capital, which is concretely fictitious.

  5. “… Schnabel’s ‘last mile’ is more like a horizon that she will never reach.” -> With conventional peak oil in 2008 (Page 45, Outlook 2018 by the International Energy Agency), crude and condensate peak in 2018 (Peak Oil Barrel blog), Saudi Arabia ditching its plans to reach 13 million barrels of production by 2027 (in the news) and with Permian Basin light tight oil starting to decline (Art Berman blog), being ENERGY the source of value of the industrial society, being OIL production the physical manifestation of energy, and as in a capitalist economy DEMAND adjust to OFFER by PRICE, we may conclude, without “The shadow of a doubt” (Hitchcock, Cotten, Wright, 1943), that Frau Schnabel will become Frau VOLCKER sooner than later. Or not, because as James D. Hamilton (Professor of Economics, University of California, San Diego) explains in “Oil Prices and the Economic Downturn” when oil purchases reach 5 % of US GDP the economy enters a recession (nowadays at U$S 120 a barrel).

  6. Le bénéfice n’est pas le profit . Ce dernier est une notion comptable, alors que le profit est une catégorie économique et il peut y avoir une augmentation du profit en masse, tout en ayant un taux inférieur.

  7. Just to be sure that nobody confuses my riffing on a paragraph in an essay with what Lapavitis might say about this situation were he asked. CL is clear that money is endogenous (his “as it were” is much clearer throughout) and both he and I agree with VK on that. My off-the-cuff comments came from wondering if a large, one-time injection of fiat money might have differential effects on the functions of money, as the quote implies. As VK says, the functions themselves are not independent and separate (except theoretically), but that doesn’t necessarily mean that any given intervention would effect them all equally or in ways that would net out in terms of the immediate impact on the economy as a whole or the differing interests of workers and capitalists. I crawled further out on the limb by wondering if a central bank might be able to exploit those differential impacts. It would know, for example, that furloughed workers would be unable to make rent and that this would be harmful for both them and the landlords. And it might choose to intervene to maintain that chain of exchange, knowing as UCBP says that workers will not hoard the money, and despite knowing that the cash injection would contribute at least a bit to higher inflation. 

    Anyway, everything after “My off the cuff…” in me musing on the post, the quote and the comment. All of which is, I suppose, a roundabout way of saying it’s not Lapavitsis’ fault. 

  8. More data on this “last mile”:

    <blockquote class=”twitter-tweet”><p lang=”en” dir=”ltr”>The USA is in a de facto state of war economy. Won't work this time. <a href=”https://t.co/dKaIAljxvx”>https://t.co/dKaIAljxvx</a></p>&mdash; VK News (@vkamikazes) <a href=”https://twitter.com/vkamikazes/status/1757576489006977078?ref_src=twsrc%5Etfw”>February 14, 2024</a></blockquote> <script async src=”https://platform.twitter.com/widgets.js” charset=”utf-8″></script>

    Now we know the true importance of this USD 95 billion package for the Ukraine, Israel and Taiwan: a big chunk of that money will revert back to American industry.

    Why does “recycling” money to the war industry works better than simply giving the American people money? Because, contrary to the rest of the sector, America’s military sector is still basically intact, so money applied to this specific sector will foment industrialization in the country.

    The same is (even more) true when the USA forces its allies (provinces) to ramp up their own border tensions and thus buy more American weaponry and related equipment, because it has monopoly of the sector.

    P.S.: The working class, as we already know, exists through simple reproduction C – M – C, so everything given to them they will spend unproductively. The US Government has nothing to consistently gain from giving them free money: that pandemic boost was only possible because it covered an unknown unknown, because it helped save many businesses that depended on constant consuming from the working class and because of the Dollar Standard, which can force the rest of the world to keep the supply chains more open than the normal through money printing (Donald Trump was printing something to the tune of USD 1.1 trillion per quarter during 2020). If the trend became perpetual, labor power would get more expensive because the subsistence level would increase (from pov of the “private sector”), thus making the industrial reserve army relatively smaller, thus putting more upwards pressure on wages, which would make the profit rates fall. The debate of a Universal Basic Income is only taken seriously in Western Europe, and only because it is ventilated as a substitute to the Welfare State, not as a complement to it, which would make it profitable to those national economies. In the rest of the world, where the Welfare State doesn’t exist, it doesn’t even cross the imagination.

Leave a comment

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.