Not before the sun burns out

This year’s Historical Materialism conference in London seemed well attended and with younger participants.  HM covers all aspects of radical thought: philosophical, political, cultural, psychological and economic.  But it’s economics that this blog concentrates on and so my account of HM London will be similar.

Actually, there did not seem to be as many economic sessions as in previous years, so let me begin with the ones that I organised!  They were the two book launch sessions: one on the new book, The World in Crisis, edited by Guglielmo Carchedi and myself; and the second on my short book, Marx 200, that elaborates on Marx’s key economics ideas and their relevance in the 21st century, some 200 years after his birth and 150 years since he published Volume One of Capital.

In the session on The World in Crisis, I gave a general account of the various chapters that all aim at providing a global empirical analysis of Marx’s law of profitability, with the work of mostly young authors from Europe, Asia, North and South America (not Africa, unfortunately). World in Crisis

As the preface in the book says: World in Crisis aims to provide empirical validity to the hypothesis that the cause of recurring and regular economic crises or slumps in output, investment and employment can be found ultimately in Marx’s law of the tendential fall in the rate of profit on capital.  My power point presentation showed one overall result: that wherever you look at the data globally, there has been a secular fall in the rate of profit on capital; and in several chapters there is evidence that the causal driver of crises under capitalism is a fall in profitability and profits.

In the session, Tony Norfield presented his chapter on derivatives and capital markets.  Tony has just published his powerpoint presentation on his excellent blog site here.  Tony traces the origin of the rise of derivatives from the 1990s to the instability of capital markets. Derivatives did not cause the global financial crash in 2008 but by extending the speculative boom in credit in the early 2000s, they helped spread the crash beyond the borders of the US and connecting the crash in the home markets to mortgages, commodities and sovereign debt.  Tony argued finance is now dominant in the controlling and distributing value globally but that still does not mean that finance can escape the laws of motion of capital and profitability.  On the contrary, finance intensifies the crisis of profitability.  So, in policy terms, acting to regulate or take over banking and finance will not be enough to change anything.

Brian Green stepped in to fill the slot for my fellow editor Guglielmo Carchedi who was unable to make the session.  Brian offered an intriguing new insight on how to measure the rate of profit on capital that could include circulating as well as fixed assets.  Most Marxists consider that it is impossible to properly measure circulating capital to add into the denominator in Marx’s rate of profit formula (s/(c+v)  Brian offers a method using national accounts to achieve this and, in so doing, he argued that a much more precise measure of the rate of profit can be achieved that will enable us to see more accurately any changes in profits and investment that would lead to a slump.

Some important questions were asked by the audience.  In particular, how can we connect Marx’s law of profitability (the rate of profit) with crises based on a falling mass of profit?  In Chapter One of the book, Carchedi and I show just that: that a falling rate of profit eventually leads to a fall in the mass of profit (or a fall in total new value) which triggers the collapse in investment.

Indeed, contrary to the view of Keynesians that a fall in household consumption triggers a crisis, it is investment that swings down, not consumption.  In the Great Recession, profits led investment which led GDP; consumption hardly moved.  Here is a graph showing the change in investment and consumption one year before each post-war slump in the US.

Another question was: why do bourgeois economists find a rise in the rate of profit from the early 1980s if Marx’s law is right?  The answer is two-fold: first, while Marx’s law holds that there will be a secular fall in profitability, it will not be in a straight line and there will be periods when the counteracting factors (eg. a rising rate of surplus value) to the law as such (a rising organic composition of capital) will be stronger.  And second, this was the case for the so-called neoliberal period from the early 1980s to the end of the century.  So mainstream measures, which always start at the beginning of the 1980s, miss part of the picture.

In the session on the book Marx 200, in my presentation, Marx 200 HM, I again outlined what I consider are the key laws of motion of capitalism that Marx revealed in his economic analysis: the law of value, the law of accumulation and the law of profitability.  The latter flows from the first two, so Marx’s theory of crises depends on all three laws being correct.  At the session, Riccardo Bellofiore of the University of Bergamo, kindly agreed to offer a critique of the book and my approach.  Riccardo considered that my emphasis on using empirical data and official statistics bordered on a ‘logical positivist’, undialectical method.  As Paul Mattick, the great Marxist economist of the 1950 and 1960s argued, it was impossible to use official data based only in fiat money terms to ascertain the changes in value in Marxist terms.  Moreover, my emphasis on data and economic trends was too ‘determinist’ and failed to take account of the role of working class struggle.  Not everything can be decided by economic forces, there was also the subjective role of the class and I was dismissing this.

Naturally I disagree.  It seems to me that ‘scientific socialism’ is just that: a scientific approach to explaining the irreconcilable contradiction within capitalism and why it needs to be and must be replaced with socialism if human society is to progress or even survive.  Marx recognised the role of empirical data in his backing up his theories and often attempted with the limited resources at his disposal to accumulate such (in Capital and elsewhere).   We cannot just assert that Marx’s laws of motion must be right because there are recurrent crises in capitalism – we have to show that it is Marx’s laws that lie behind these crises and not other explanations.  If correct, other explanations might (and do) mean that capitalism just needs ‘modification’ or ‘management’ (Keynes) or even better left alone (neoclassical and Austrian).

It is not determinist to argue that economic conditions are out of the conscious control of both capitalists and workers (an Invisible Leviathan) and the law of motion of capitalism will override the ability of people in struggle to irreversibly change their lives – without the ending of capitalism.  Class struggle operates continually, but its degree of intensity and the level of success for labour over capital will be partly (even mainly) determined by the economic conditions. Men make their own history, but they do not make it as they please; they do not make it under self-selected circumstances, but under circumstances existing” (Marx).

A number of other important issues were raised by the audience:  what about the three laws that Uno Kozo, the Japanese Marxist economist identified?  I cannot answer this one but there was a session at HM on just that with Elene Lange.

The other question that came up was again whether Marx’s law of profitability was really just a secular theory (ie long term) and basically irrelevant as offering any underlying cause of recurrent crises; or whether it was just a cyclical theory, explaining the ‘business cycle’ or ‘waves of capital accumulation’, and has nothing to say about the eventual demise or breakdown of capitalism.

It was Rosa Luxemburg’s view that it was the former – a very long-term tendency that was so long term that the ‘sun would burn out’ before a falling rate of profit would play a role in pushing capitalism into crises (Luxemburg made this remark sarcastically in reply to a Russian economist who suggested that Marx’s law of profitability might well be relevant).  On the other hand, many Marxist economists who do accept the relevance of Marx’s law of profitability in recurrent crises deny that it offers a prediction for the transient future of capitalism (ie capitalism cannot last forever).  In my view, the law is both secular and cyclical and I present arguments for this view in my book, The Long Depression.  And in the new book, The World in Crisis, there is evidence of both the secular view (Maito) and the cyclical view (Tapia).

Enough of my sessions, because it would be amiss not mention several good sessions on Latin America (Mariano Feliz, Angus McNelly); and looking back at Marx’s value theory
(Andy Higginbottom (Higginbottom2012JAPEpublished),
Heesang Jeon Value_Use_Value_Needs_and_the_Social_Div).
I shall be returning to these topics on my blog over the next period.

Finally, there was the Isaac Deutscher Memorial Prize awarded at HM for the best Marxist book of the year.  Last year’s winner was William Clare Roberts for his intriguing Marx’s Inferno: The Political Theory of Capital (Princeton UP).  For my initial thoughts on this work, see here. But last week, after hearing my namesake speak on the subject of the nature of freedom under socialism, I shall be returning to this subject in a future post.

The shortlist for 2018 was:

Sven-Eric Liedman, A World to Win: The Life and Works of Karl Marx (Verso)
Kim Moody, On New Terrain: How Capital is Reshaping the Battleground of Class War (Haymarket Books)
Kohei Saito, Karl Marx’s Ecosocialism: Capital, Nature, and the Unfinished Critique of Political Economy (Monthly Review)
Ranabir Samaddar, Karl Marx and the Postcolonial Age (Palgrave Macmillan)

Advertisements

9 Responses to “Not before the sun burns out”

  1. Anti-Capital Says:

    ” The rate of profit would not fall under the effect of competition due to over-production of capital. It would rather be the reverse; it would be the competitive struggle which would begin because the fallen rate of profit and over-production of capital originate from the same conditions.” Capital Vol 3, Ch 15

  2. mandm Says:

    Michael, you were right to characterize Luxemburg’s comment on tarp as sarcastic (not really opposing the theory, but rather reactionary orthodoxy under revolutionary circumstances). But we should appreciate the historical insight beneath her sarcasm. Your graph showing capitalism’s secular falling rate of profit from 1863 to 2007 might also serve, if turned upside down, as a political/cultural graph of the increasing rate of barbaric destruction of human beings, wealth, and the natural environment under evolving industrial/imperial capitalism. She was expressing her exasperation with “marxists” whose practice expressed more comfort with the prospect of barbarism than with socialism.

    If capital is a social relation, which can only be understood historically, our perspective has to be from that of social reproduction rather than one strictly from the production process. The former was Luxemburg’s perspective. Your blog’s emphasis on the economic is good strategy and very much needed, to say nothing about the links you supply, but it would be good if we had more responses, and positive ones, from writers like Higgenbottom.

  3. Elena Louisa Lange Says:

    I just posted a long commentary and wonder it has gone.

  4. Elena Says:

    Hi Michael, I try to reconstruct some of the things that I said previously. First of all, thanks for the mention. I shall say however that my panel with Andy Higginbottom et al. did not thematise the ‘three laws’ in Uno, but, among other things, went into the intricacies of the trafo-problem, and the relation between the labour and the monetary theory of value. Since you announced you’d be referring to some of the things Andy said in the next post, let me just give you a small feedback on the panel and Andy’s talk. Andy’s talk more or less referred to the methodological structure of Capital, “New Dialectic”- (Arthur,Reuten)-style, the alleged tripartite structure of particular, general and universal (including the contested concept of ‘capital in general’) taking place in the unfolding of Marx’s argument – to which Michael Heinrich (who was present), and correctly I think, objected that Marx had only used this Hegelian tripartite framework in the Grundrisse, and never again referred to ‘capital in general’ after the 1861-63 manuscript which it is difficult to defend this as the framework for the methodological unfolding of Capital. The editorial niceties aside, what do you think of Andy’s critique of Moseley’s ‘Money and Totality’? I especially couldn’t get my head around the argument, forwarded by Andy, that Moseley was wrong in emphasising the possibility of a non-convergence of the value power and wage (which is of course the signature thesis of the NI), because, I quote, “labour power is not a bearer of profit”. While it is true that labour power is not a bearer of profit, the value of labour power, which alone can be expressed in prices of production, OF COURSE IS A BEARER OF PROFIT. I asked Andy about what he meant, but my question was left unanswered. In the same vein, I would like to hear more about what Moseley’s alleged ‘confusion’ between the ‘distribution’ and the ‘realisation’ of surplus value consists in, and get maybe Andy to participate, and hear what you have to say on this. As for the LTRPF, I am currently peer reviewing an interesting (but IMO wrong) paper on the paradox of the co-existence of a rising ROP with secular stagnation in the current Japanese economy. Will maybe be able to announce some details soon.

  5. Nadim Mahjoub Says:

    Hi, Michael! What is your take on Wallerstein’s “world-system theory”?

  6. Carlos Rodrigo Zapata Says:

    In Marx’s time, the possibility that the fall in the rate of profit could lead to a generalized bankruptcy of the capitalist system was very shocking. Nowadays expecting something like that is downright ridiculous. In this context, Rosa Luximburgo’s phrase must be taken almost verbatim, except that we will never have the opportunity to see how the sun dies or goes out because before the planet earth will have succumbed, prey to its own contradictions,

    Nowadays we can no longer continue dealing with the fall of the rate of profit to diagnose how capitalism is doing. Today, the essential problem is that of planetary ecological limits. The rate of profit has continued to fall but it does not fare badly, thanks to the immense and colossal forces that counteract the fall in the rate of profit, but the planet is getting worse and worse, proof of the serious incompatibility between the capitalist system and the planetary system. .

    It is a conclusion, it is time to take care of quickly dismantling this system that is already about to take us beyond the point of no return.

Leave a Reply

Fill in your details below or click an icon to log in:

WordPress.com Logo

You are commenting using your WordPress.com account. Log Out /  Change )

Google+ photo

You are commenting using your Google+ account. Log Out /  Change )

Twitter picture

You are commenting using your Twitter account. Log Out /  Change )

Facebook photo

You are commenting using your Facebook account. Log Out /  Change )

Connecting to %s

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.


%d bloggers like this: