China’s transition: new leaders, old policies

The 18th National Congress of the Communist Party of China has just finished in Beijing.  Xi Jinping, 59, and Li Keqiang, 57, will take over.  The debate within the leadership will continue about which way to take China: towards a full market economy open to the winds of global capital flows or to stay as they are.  The view of the media and ‘experts’ in the West seems to be that the new seven-man (and they are all men – see below) standing committee is broadly in favour of the status quo: dont’ rock the boat.  If it works, don’t fix it.  Sure, the new leader Xi talks about getting closer to the people, bearing down on corruption, reducing inequality etc.  But so do all Chinese leaders say this when they take over.    There is no evidence that Xi will do any of this, or even move in any radical way towards American-style capitalism.
Old and new – spot the difference!
Xi’s father Xi Zhongxun was a reform-minded Communist leader who was purged during the Cultural Revolution. Restored by Deng Xiaoping, he became the governor of Guangdong where he contributed to the pioneering economic reforms of Shenzhen in the 1980s.   Xi has been promoted by the Shanghai faction of the Party, known for its market-driven focus, and former President Jiang Zemin. But he also rests upon the more ‘conservative’ faction like Hu Jintao and Communist Youth League (CYL).  Xi emphasises the need for “collective responsibility” which he defined as the absence of individual interests among the party members. ie let’s stick together.

A year ago, when Beijing was pondering the 12th 5-year plan, Xi  supported an acceleration of ‘economic reforms’, namely the new growth model presented in the “China 2030” project with the Chinese State Council and the World Bank.  This report (see my previous post of last March, http://thenextrecession.wordpress.com/2012/03/23/which-way-for-china-part-two/) is a clear step towards an outright market economy that drastically reduces the role of the state and opens up the domestic economy to foreign capital even more.  The argument of the Sinology ‘experts’ of mainstream economics is that only this will enable China to escape from the so-called ‘middle income trap’.  They mean that, to begin with, ‘emerging economies’ can grow fast with big capital investment and exports using cheap labour and new technology – the Chinese model.

But less than a fifth of the 180 countries in the world have made it to being advanced economies. This chart, from the World Bank’s report makes the same point. Of the 101 countries that were “middle-income” in 1960, only 13 had managed to break from the pack to become advanced economies by 2008.

World Bank chart

One reason why countries get stuck in this “middle-income trap” is that they reach what is known as the “Lewis Point“, after the left economist of the 1950s, Arthur Lewis.  Put simply, this is the point at which a developing country stops being able to achieve rapid growth relatively easily, by simply taking rural workers doing unproductive farm labour and putting them to work in factories and cities instead.  But once this ‘reserve army of labour’ is exhausted, urban wages rise, incomes reach a certain level and a ‘middle-class’ emerges.  Distorting Lewis’ theory, mainstream economics asserts that then there must be a switch to boosting domestic consumption that a state-led economy cannot do.  So the cry is “Liberalise with free trade and capital – that’s the only way to move on”.  Typical of these arguments are the comments of  James McGregor, author of the 2012 book “No Ancient Wisdom, No Followers: The Challenges of Authoritarian Capitalism.” He commented “China’s done well in building infrastructure and getting the nation where it is but state industry is choking off economic growth so they have to re-ignite private industry.”

But the new Chinese leaders are divided on what direction to take.  For example, one of the new leaders is Zhang Dejiang from Sichuan province who wants keep things as they are.  For him, state-owned enterprises must strive to be “stronger, more excellent and bigger,”. Under his watch, some private auto companies including Zhejiang Gonow Auto Co. were merged into state-run competitors in a process described in Chinese as “the state advances and the private sector retreats.”  And state-run companies still dominate.   In another leader, Zhang Gaoli’s city, the indebted state-owned Tianjin City Infrastructure Construction & Investment Group has projects including construction of a new financial district modeled on Manhattan. It sold a 3 billion yuan ($481 million) one-year note in March at a 4.36 percent coupon, 220 basis points below the one-year bank lending rate at the time.  By contrast, small entrepreneurs in Tianjin can get unsecured loans for 2 percent interest per month, or more than 26 percent a year, according to the 3g210.com website, which provides loan interest rate information.  This is not what the Western capitalist ‘experts’ want to see.

And Left economist John Ross takes a different view (http://ablog.typepad.com/keytrendsinglobalisation/2012/10/investment-will-boost-chinas-economy.html).  Raising consumption – i.e. living standards indeed should be economic policy’s aim.  But unfortunately< Ross argues, this became confused with a different idea of sharply increasing the percentage of consumption in China’s GDP. These two goals are actually contradictory as GDP growth is largely driven by investment, and this underpins sustainable consumption.  But sharply increasing consumption’s percentage in GDP cuts investment levels, thereby inadvertently leading to lower GDP and consequently lower consumption growth.  This  illustrates why the phrase ‘consumer-led growth’ is confused.

China has grown by just under 10% a year, on average, since 1980. If it can grow by at least 6% or 6.5% a year from now on, the World Bank reckons it can graduate to become a high-income country before 2030 and overtake the US as the world’s largest economy. (China’s income per head, of course, would still be much lower than America’s.)  But this is by no means guaranteed.  Every developed economy has made this fundamental transition. But few, if any, have done it while continuing to increase productivity – output per head – by 6-7% a year. America, Europe and Japan had the advantage of a growing labour force for most of this stage in their development. China will not. Its population is ageing much more rapidly and its labour force will be shrinking after 2016.

How can we judge  whether China will continue to grow at that sort of rate?  In my earlier post, I argued that China cannot be seen as just another capitalist economy,.  But even so, the law of value does operate in China, mainly through foreign trade and capital inflows, as well as through domestic markets for consumption goods, services and funds.  In so far as it does, profitability becomes key to investment and growth.  So what has happened to China’s profitability in the last 30 years?  There have been various attempts to estimate the rate of profit in China.  I did so in my book, The Great Recession, chapter 12.  There are other studies that reach slightly different conclusions than I did (Zhang Yu and Zhao Feng, 2006, www.seruc.com/bgl/paper%202006/Zhao-Zhang.pdf; and Mylene Gaulard, 2010, http://gesd.free.fr/m6gaulard.pdf ).

I found that there were three cycles of profitability.  Between 1978-90, there was an upswing as capitalist production expanded through the Deng reforms and the opening up of foreign trade.  But from 1990 to the end of that decade, there was a decline, as over-investment gathered pace and other economies, particularly in the emerging world went through a series of crises (Mexico 1994, Asia 1997-8, Latin America 1998-01).  The falling rate of profit then was accompanied by slowing in the rate of GDP growth.  Then from about 1999 onwards, there was a rise in profitability, which also saw a significant rise in the rate of China’s economic growth (as the world too expanded at a credit-fuelled pace).

We are now getting better data from China to work with and I have just done further work on the Chinese rate of profit.  It looks as though profitability peaked in 2004.

After 2007, the slump in world capitalism drove down Chinese profitability.  Rising wages were not matched by increased sales abroad, so the rate of surplus value slumped (green line) while investment in fixed capital remained high (red line).  So profitability fell.

Inevitably, this has had a deleterious effect on GDP growth, as profits lead investment and investment leads growth, particularly in China.

Globalisation and the law of value in world markets feed through to the Chinese economy.  And the effect has been pernicious for the majority of Chinese.   Inequality of wealth and income under China’s ‘socialism with Chinese characteristics’ has never been so bad.  China’s Gini coefficient, an index of income inequality, according to Sun Liping, a professor at Beijing’s Tsinghua University, has risen from 0.30 in 1978 when the Communist Party began to open the economy to market force 0.46.  (and see my recent post on this)  China’s Gini coefficient has risen more than any other Asian economy in the last two decades.  The rise in inequality is partly the result of the urbanisation of the economy as rural peasants move to the cities.  Urban wages in the sweatshops and factories are increasing, leaving peasant incomes behind (not that those urban wages are anything to write home about when workers assembling Apple i-pads are paid under $2 an hour).  But it is also partly the result of the elite controlling the levers of power and making themselves fat, while allowing some Chinese billionaires to flourish.

Is mainstream economics right to argue that people’s needs and aspirations can only be met by a capitalist economy?  The evidence of the Great Recession and the ensuing long depression suggests otherwise.  If the capitalist road is adopted by the new leaders and the law of value becomes dominant, it will expose the Chinese people to chronic economic instability (booms and slumps), insecurity of employment and income and greater inequalities.  On the other hand, if the surplus created by the Chinese people remains under the control of an elite backed by an army and police and ruling without dissent, then the needs and aspirations of a more affluent and educated population will not be met.  The key to continued growth and more equality will be democracy.  China needs to move from so-called ‘socialism with Chinese characteristics’ (i.e. a state-led economy under a corrupt autocracy) to a China with socialist foundations (democratic planning and equality).  China cannot just stay as it is, whatever its new leaders might hope.

About these ads

6 Responses to “China’s transition: new leaders, old policies”

  1. Systemic Disorder Says:

    China surely can’t stay as it is. Moving to “a China with socialist foundations” would require a revolution among the most thorough-going the world has ever seen as not only the CCP elite, its aligned business elites and, let us not forget, the mutli-national corporations that profit enormously from Chinese sweatshop labor have core interests in maintaining it.

    Government spending on investment is at unsustainable levels, wages are too low for Chinese workers to buy anything beyond a tiny fraction of what they produce and even China will eventually run out of displaced farm workers to maintain an urban sweatshop labor force. The whole thing is dependent on massive exporting, and it can’t be expected that the rest of the world will allow itself to be flooded with Chinese products forever, especially given chronic high unemployment across the advanced capitalist countries.

    The multi-nationals that have transferred production to China do so on the basis of the minuscule wages and lack of effective labor laws (admittedly to gain access to China as well). But if Chinese workers succeed in dramatically raising their wages, much of that production might well head for Vietnam or Bangladesh. If they don’t, then China remains completely dependent on exports and much more unrest will follow.

    Chinese workers have a gigantic task ahead of them.

  2. Cameron Says:

    China will stay as is, that is a capitalist state. The surplus created by state owned enterprises will continue to be siphoned off to the ruling elite, which is part of the capitalist class, via corruption at all levels. The party elites are billionaires. If you think that they’d give up their wealth and status for a socialist China then you’re in for a big surprise. China, like all other value-form societies will slump into recessions. It’s already underway.

    It might be that the ruling elite is fanning the nationalistic fervor to channel worker’s frustrations towards Japan and other countries. They seem to have succeeded but for now.

  3. Warren Ward Says:

    I should be very interested to hear your views on Richard Duncan’s in-depth interview in the latest edition of New Left Review (main article). I understand that you are bombarded with such requests, but he makes the bold claim that our dominant global economic system can no longer be described as capitalism. Duncan also suggests some solutions that may help us emerge from this long depression and I wondered what you would say in response? Thanks, as ever, for your most enlightening and interesting blog.

    • michael roberts Says:

      Duncan, like many economists who adopt either an Austrian theory of economic crisis or a Minksy-Keynesian view, reckons that crises are caused by excessive credit or debt and that there is nothing wrong with the mode of capitalist production. Duncan reckons the crisis is one of ‘creditism’ not capitalism, rather similar to the Austrians (who blame excessive government intervention by central banks) or excessive private credit created by banks (Steve Keen) or privatised Keynesianism created by the finance sector (Riccardo Bellofiore).

      My view (which you can glean from a host of my posts) is that the huge expansion of credit and fictitious capital (Marxist term) was the product of the falling profitability in the capitalist accumulation process, so the underlying cause of crises is to be found in the capitalist mode of production, even if the proximate (or immediate) cause was a banking crash, a credit crunch etc. Now the huge weight dead capital and debt weighs down on capitalist profitability and economic recovery.

      Duncan seems to suggest writing off debt both in the private and public sector as a solution. That’s certainly part of the answer, although that policy is totally unacceptable to the financial sector, which is very powerful. So it is naive. Anyway, it’s not enough. ‘Controlling credit’, the cry of Keynesians, Minskyites and Austrians, ignores the contradictions in capitalist accumulation. So future crises would not be avoided and the whole ‘crap’ (Marx’s word) would be repeated.

  4. Warren Ward Says:

    Thank you Michael.

  5. purple Says:

    The reason middle income countries can’t get rich is because of imperialism, in all its forms. Taiwan and South Korea stand out as examples simply because of the support they received from the U.S. a counterweight to then red China.

Leave a Reply

Fill in your details below or click an icon to log in:

WordPress.com Logo

You are commenting using your WordPress.com account. Log Out / Change )

Twitter picture

You are commenting using your Twitter account. Log Out / Change )

Facebook photo

You are commenting using your Facebook account. Log Out / Change )

Google+ photo

You are commenting using your Google+ account. Log Out / Change )

Connecting to %s


Follow

Get every new post delivered to your Inbox.

Join 1,442 other followers

%d bloggers like this: